32
econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW – Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW – Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. Terms of use: Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your personal and scholarly purposes. You are not to copy documents for public or commercial purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. If the documents have been made available under an Open Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. zbw Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Danao, Rolando A. Working Paper Market power in the Philippine power market Discussion paper // School of Economics, University of the Philippines, No. 2009,09 Provided in Cooperation with: University of the Philippines School of Economics (UPSE) Suggested Citation: Danao, Rolando A. (2009) : Market power in the Philippine power market, Discussion paper // School of Economics, University of the Philippines, No. 2009,09 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/46652

core.ac.uk · The Philippine electricity market is in a period of transition as the restructuring provisions of the Electric ... company, the Power Sector ... monopolistic to a

  • Upload
    lydang

  • View
    214

  • Download
    2

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

econstor www.econstor.eu

Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW – Leibniz-Informationszentrum WirtschaftThe Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW – Leibniz Information Centre for Economics

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:

Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichenZwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.

Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielleZwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglichmachen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.

Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dortgenannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.

Terms of use:

Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for yourpersonal and scholarly purposes.

You are not to copy documents for public or commercialpurposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make thempublicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwiseuse the documents in public.

If the documents have been made available under an OpenContent Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), youmay exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicatedlicence.

zbw Leibniz-Informationszentrum WirtschaftLeibniz Information Centre for Economics

Danao, Rolando A.

Working Paper

Market power in the Philippine power market

Discussion paper // School of Economics, University of the Philippines, No. 2009,09

Provided in Cooperation with:University of the Philippines School of Economics (UPSE)

Suggested Citation: Danao, Rolando A. (2009) : Market power in the Philippine power market,Discussion paper // School of Economics, University of the Philippines, No. 2009,09

This Version is available at:http://hdl.handle.net/10419/46652

UP School of Economics

Discussion Papers

UPSE Discussion Papers are preliminary versions circulated privately to elicit critical comments. They are protected by Copyright Law (PD No. 49)

and are not for quotation or reprinting without prior approval.

*Professor Emeritus, UP School of Economics

Discussion Paper No. 2009-09 September 2009

Market Power in the Philippine Power Market

by

ROLANDO A. DANAO*

1

MARKET POWER IN THE PHILIPPINE POWER MARKET

by

Rolando A. Danao

Abstract

The Philippine electricity market is in a period of transition as the restructuring provisions of the Electric Power

Industry Reform Act (EPIRA) of 2001 are being implemented. Under current structure, the market is highly

concentrated, indicating the existence of market power. In addition, many plants, including small ones, become

pivotal suppliers during peak hours, creating opportunities for the exercise of market power. Concentration in the

spot market is even more pronounced as a large percentage of uncontracted capacity belongs to the Independent

Power Producers (IPP) with NPC contracts whose energy outputs are under the control of a single company, the

Power Sector Assets and Liabilities Management Corporation. This highlights the urgency of speeding up the

dominance mitigating provision of EPIRA, namely, the appointment of independent IPP administrators who will

trade the IPP outputs in the wholesale market.

2

MARKET POWER IN THE PHILIPPINE POWER MARKET

1. INTRODUCTION

The delivery of electricity has four components: (1) generation at power plants, (2) transmission through

overhead high-voltage wires to stations near population centers, (3) distribution through low-voltage wires to its

users, and (4) retail consisting of metering, billing, and collection of payments1. These components were bundled

and managed as a vertically integrated monopoly because (a) it was argued that integration could lower the costs of

operations and (b) electrical equilibrium2 required by the electrical network could be effectively managed by a

single company. This meant that government regulation was necessary; in fact, the government in many countries

owned the monopoly. Under this setup, the price of electricity was regulated and because electricity was regarded as

a basic commodity which should be accessible to all people, some governments made electricity available with

government subsidy.

This was the model of the electricity industry (with some variations in different countries3) until 1978 when

Chile pioneered the idea of introducing competition in the generation sector. But the first substantial and wide-

ranging reform of the electricity industry took place in 1990 when the United Kingdom split its power stations into

two competing companies, privatized most of the industry, allowed large consumers direct access to the grid,

allowed generators free entry to the industry, opened access to the transmission lines, and established the wholesale

electricity pool. More countries and states soon followed, including, among others, Norway (1990), Argentina

(1992), Singapore (1995), California (1996), Spain (1997), Australia (1998) and the Philippines (2001). Although

reforms varied from country to country in extent and market design, they were all instituted to shift from the

monopolistic to a competitive structure. A common feature of electricity industry restructuring is the establishment

of the wholesale electricity market.

1 It is not unusual to list only three components since retail has traditionally been a part of distribution.

2 Electrical equilibrium means that production and consumption of electricity must be equal at all times.

3 In the Philippines, generation and transmission were operated by the state-controlled National Power Corporation (NPC) while

distribution and retail were operated by privately owned companies such as MERALCO.

3

2. THE WHOLESALE ELECTRICITY MARKET

The wholesale electricity market (or competitive pool) was created to introduce competition in the

generation component of the electricity industry. It is an auction market for the bulk trading of electricity where

generators compete to sell electricity in a centralized pool and distributors and bulk consumers buy from the pool.

The competitive pool may be organized as a gross pool (or mandatory pool), which is to say that all generators are

required to sell all their electricity outputs in the pool and all buyers of electricity buy from the pool (e.g., Argentina

and the Philippines). This market design allows financial bilateral contracts between buyers and sellers as hedges

against the volatility of spot price outcomes but the physical flows of power are all within the pool. In contrast,

buyers and sellers in a net pool (or voluntary pool) can enter into physical bilateral trading of electricity outside the

pool (e.g., Spain and California). But whether the pool is mandatory or voluntary, pool price is determined by

similar auction rules.

2.1. Price Determination in the Wholesale Electricity Market

In a competitive pool, generators compete to supply electricity by submitting price-quantity offers

indicating the amount of electricity they are willing to generate at various prices during a trading period. The Market

Operator (MO) arranges these offers in a supply curve by increasing order of price (called the merit order). The

buyers compete to purchase electricity through price-quantity bids which are arranged by the MO in a demand curve

by decreasing order of price. For each trading period, the MO determines the equilibrium price-quantity pair, being

the intersection of the supply and demand curves. The equilibrium price, also called the market-clearing price, sets

the system market price for the trading period. If the market is designed as a uniform price auction market, as in the

Philippines, then all winning supply offers are paid the system market price.

In some wholesale electricity markets, (e.g., the Philippines) demand side bidding is not developed. In this

case, the Market Operator (MO) forecasts total load 4, say Q0, and uses the vertical line Q = Q0 as the demand curve.

The MO then proceeds to dispatch supply offers in increasing order of price and the last offer dispatched to meet the

forecasted load sets the system market price. To illustrate (see Figure 1), let the forecasted load be Q0. Starting with

the lowest bid price P1, the MO uses up all quantities offered at price P1. Then he goes to the next lowest price P2

and uses up all quantities offered at P2. He continues in this fashion and ends at the highest price Pk when Q0 is fully

covered. The market-clearing price Pk is the system market price that every seller will receive and every buyer will

pay.

4 “Load” is the electricity industry term for quantity demanded.

4

Figure 1. Price Determination in the Wholesale Electricity Market with No Demand Side Bids

0

MarketClearingPrice

P1

P2

Pk

Q1

Total Load

Q2 Q0

The generators supplying electricity are usually located far from the demand areas. This means that the costs of

providing electricity to different locations (nodes5) differ due to different transmission capacity constraint conditions

and different transmission losses. Therefore, the system market price is adjusted to reflect transmission congestion

and transmission losses, resulting in nodal prices.6

2.2. Special Characteristics of the Electricity Market

As a commodity, electricity has certain characteristics that other commodities do not possess. First,

electricity cannot be stored (or very costly to store) in large quantities; hence, no inventory is available as an

alternative supply source. Second, the production and consumption of electricity must be balanced at every point in

time. Third, demand is price inelastic, i.e., there is very little real-time demand response to price changes. Fourth,

supply is capacity constrained and significant additions to supply still require substantial lead times. These unusual

characteristics of the electricity market make it highly susceptible to the exercise of market power.

3. MARKET POWER

Market power is the ability of a firm, or group of firms acting together, to raise prices above competitive

levels. Market power abuse happens when this power is exercised to raise prices through manipulation. Why is the

exercise of market power of great concern?

5 A node is a point in the electrical network where electricity is either supplied to or withdrawn from the network.

6 Chile, Argentina, and the Philippines use nodal pricing. In zonal pricing, nodes are grouped into zones (e.g., Norway, California).

5

The stakes are enormous as value added in the electricity industry is substantial. For example, in 2005,

value added in the electricity industry in the Philippines was estimated at P148.1 billion which accounted for 2.7%

of the Gross Domestic Product (NSO [2007]; NSCB [2008]). In such a market, any exercise of market power can

result in large wealth transfers from consumers to producers of electricity. Moreover, such transfers can occur within

very short periods of time (see Wolak [2000] for the California example).

3.1. Capacity Withholding: A Strategy for Exercising Market Power

One of the strategies for exercising market power is to reduce the supply of electricity through physical or

economic withholding of capacity. Physical withholding refers to the reduction of the supply of electricity by

declaring an outage or by simply refusing to generate electricity. To prevent physical withholding, some markets

(e.g., the Philippines) prescribe a “must offer” rule which requires every generator to offer its maximum available

capacity. Despite this rule, it is still possible to withhold capacity by economic withholding. This is done by offering

a block of electricity at a price sufficiently high that it will not be dispatched. The effect is, of course, the same as

that of physical withholding.

The following example shows how a generating company can increase its profits by withholding some of

its capacity from the market. Let the total load be 5000 MW. Suppose there are only three generators and their

available capacities and offered prices are as given in Table 1.

Table 1. Generators’ Price-Quantity Offers (Without Capacity Withholding)

Generator Offered Capacity* (MW) Offered Price (Per MWh)

Genco A 3000 P=5000

Genco B 2000 P=6000

Genco C 1000 P=7000

*Without capacity withholding, offered capacity = available capacity.

Assume that it costs Genco A P=4000/MWh to produce electricity and the generators offer all of their available

capacities. The merit order resulting from Table 1 is given by the following dispatch schedule (see Figure 2):

6

Dispatched Capacity Bid Price

1. Genco A 3000 P=5,000/MWh

2. Genco B 2000 P=6,000/MWh (Market Clearing Price)

3. Genco C 0

Figure 2. Merit Order (Without Capacity Withholding)

P 6000

5000

P 5000

P

3000

A

2000

LOAD

MW

B

Market-Clearing P rice

The market clears at P=6,000/MWh and Genco A makes a profit of P=2000/MWh for a total profit of (3000)(P=2000) =

P=6,000,000.

Suppose that Genco A withholds 900 MW and offers 1800 MW at the same price of P=5,000/MWh and 300

MW at P=10,000/MWh. The other suppliers keep the same offers. The price-quantity offers are given in Table 2.

Table 2. Generators’ Price-Quantity Offers (With Capacity Withheld)

Generator Offered Capacity (MW) Offered Price (Per MWh)

Genco A 1800 P=5000

300 P=10000

Genco B 2000 P=6000

Genco C 1000 P=7000

7

The merit order resulting from Table 2 (see Figure 3) is given by the following dispatch schedule:

Dispatched Capacity Bid Price

1. Genco A 1800 P=5,000/MWh

2. Genco B 2000 P=6,000/MWh

3. Genco C 1000 P=7,000/MWh

4. Genco A 200 P=10,000/MWh (Market Clearing Price)

Figure 3. Merit Order after Capacity Withholding

P 10000

5000

P 5000

P

C

1000

LOAD

MW

P 6000

P 7000

A B A

1800 2002000

Market-Clearing P rice

The market clears at P=10,000/MWh and Genco A makes a profit of P=6000/MWh for a total profit of (2000)(P=6000)

= P=12,000,000, doubling its profit. Note that the other generators also benefit from Genco A’s strategy.

3.2. Detection of Market Power

In view of the susceptibility of electricity markets to the exercise of market power, it is important to

monitor the market and try to detect the existence of market power. Detection of market power distinguishes

between detection of the potential for market power and detection of the actual exercise of market power.

3.2.1. Detection of the Potential for Market Power

The Single-Firm Market Share Concentration Ratio

Until 2001, concentration measures were used as the main tool for determining the existence of market

power - the more concentrated a market, the more likely is the ability of its players to exercise market power. The

8

most concentrated market is, of course, the monopoly which sells 100% of the industry’s output. If the industry has

more than one firm, then the firms’ market shares are used to indicate concentration. The market share of a firm is

called the single-firm market share concentration ratio. The question is: what level of market share should raise

concerns about the existence of market power?

There is no widely accepted critical value for the market share level. The US Federal Energy Regulatory

Commission (FERC), up until 2001, used 20% or less as market shares that indicate lack of market power

(Borenstein [2002]). In 2004, FERC used a market power test based on the market share of uncommitted capacity

and adopted a 20% threshold, i.e., a supplier with less than 20% share of uncommitted capacity passed the test

(FERC [2004]). In the Philippines, the Electric Power Industry Reform Act (EPIRA) provides that “to promote true

market competition and prevent harmful monopoly and market power abuse, the Energy Regulatory Commission

(ERC) shall enforce the following safeguards: (a) No company or related group can own, operate or control more

than 30% of the installed generating capacity of the grid and/or 25% of the national installed generating capacity”.

These benchmarks appear to be large since there is empirical evidence that in electricity markets generation

owners with small market shares (e.g., 6%-8%) have exercised market power (Borenstein [2002]). Later in this

section, we give a hypothetical example of a market where a generator with 10% share of the market has market

power. In fact, data from the Philippine WESM show that during peak hours a small-sized generator can acquire

market power when supply is tight (see Section 5).

The Herfindahl - Hirschman Index

Market concentration does not only depend on the number of firms in the industry but also on the sizes of

the firms. Ten firms with one firm controlling 50% of the market is definitely more concentrated than ten firms of

equal size. Therefore, a good measure of concentration should reflect the number of firms and the distribution of the

sizes of the firms. One such measure is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index.

Let n be the number of firms in the market and si the percentage share of firm i. Then the Herfindahl -

Hirschman Index (HHI) is defined as

2

1

HHIn

ii

s

For the most concentrated industry, the monopoly, s1 = 100; hence, HHI = 10,000. As the number of firms increases,

HHI decreases. This is easily seen in a market consisting of n firms of equal size. In this case, s1 = s2 = ··· = sn =

100/n and

9

2 22

2

100 100 100 10000 10000HHI n

n n n n n

As n increases, HHI decreases. When n is large HHI is close to zero.

Most electricity markets have adopted the following thresholds established by the US Department of

Justice and adopted by FERC to describe levels of concentration using HHI:

Table 3. Levels of Concentration Using HHI

Highly Concentrated 1800 HHI

Moderately Concentrated 1000 HHI 1800

Unconcentrated HHI 1000

Remark. There is a tendency for regulators to assume that market power is absent in unconcentrated markets as

defined in Table 3. This assumption is not justified as the following example shows.

Example. Consider a market with only 10 suppliers, each with a capacity of 1100 MW for a total supply of 11,000

MW. Each supplier controls only 10% of the market and HHI = 10x(10)2 = 1000, indicating an unconcentrated

market. Suppose that at peak hours, total load is 10,000 MW. Then any 9 suppliers cannot meet the load since

9x1100 = 9900, 100 MW shy of total load. Every supplier is needed to meet the demand; consequently, every

supplier has monopoly power over the 100 MW residual demand. Thus, it is possible to exercise market power in

unconcentrated markets as defined in Table 3. When a supplier is needed to meet the demand, it becomes a pivotal

supplier.

The Pivotal Supplier Indicator

A supplier is said to be pivotal if the other suppliers cannot meet the demand. Thus a pivotal supplier has

monopoly power over the residual demand, that portion of the demand which cannot be covered by the other

suppliers. The Pivotal Supplier Indicator was developed by Bushnell et al. [1999])7 to indicate when a supplier is

pivotal.

7 Bushnell et al. called this indicator the Pivotal Supplier Index.

10

Let

S = total supply

Si = supply of supplier i

D = total demand

The pivotal supplier indicator for supplier i, denoted by PSIi, is defined as

0, ( is not pivotal)

1, ( is pivotal)

if S S D iiPSIi

if S S D ii

The Pivotal Supplier Frequency Index

Bushnell et al. [1999] also defined the Pivotal Supplier Frequency Index over a period of time (e.g., 24

hours) to indicate the frequency which a supplier achieves pivotal status. Let

Sh = total supply at hour h

Sih = supply of supplier i at hour h

Dh = total demand at hour h

h = 1,2, …, H (H is the number of hours in the period of interest)

Define the pivotal supplier indicator of supplier i at hour h as

0, ( is not pivotal at hour )

1, ( is pivotal at hour )

if S S D i hh ih h

PSIih if S S D i h

h ih h

Thus the sum 1

HPSI

ihh

counts the number of times i is a pivotal supplier during the period h = 1,2, ..., H.

The pivotal supplier frequency index for supplier i (PSFIi) during the period (h = 1,2, …, H) is defined as

number of times is a pivotal supplier1 100 100

HPSI

ih ihPSFIiH H

Thus, the higher the Pivotal Supplier Frequency Index the more frequent the supplier achieves pivotal status,

providing the supplier with more opportunities to exercise market power.

11

3.2.2. Detection of the Exercise of Market Power

The Lerner Index

The Lerner index, denoted by L, is based on the price-cost margin and is defined as

P MC

LP

where P = price and MC = marginal cost. The motivation for the use of the price-cost margin is that in competitive

markets, price-takers should offer at marginal cost. Hence, the difference between a generator’s offer and its

marginal cost is a measure of the exercise of market power. It turns out that the Lerner index is related to the HHI in

a Cournot market.

The Lerner Index under Cournot Competition

A Cournot market is one where firms maximize their profits by choosing quantities of output and price is

determined by the demand function. Suppose that there are n firms and let

Q = total industry output

P(Q) = the industry demand function

Qi = output of firm i

Ci(Qi) = cost function of firm i

Li = Lerner index of firm i

It can be shown (Tirole [1992]; see also Appendix A) that

*i

i

sL

where is the price elasticity of demand and si* = Qi /Q. Thus, the larger a firm’s market share or the more

inelastic the demand the greater is its market power. Under a monopoly (si* = 1) the Lerner index depends only on

the price-elasticity of demand. Under perfect competition, P = dCi /dQi = MCi ; hence, the Lerner index is zero. In a

Cournot market, the Lerner index is positive, hence, P > MCi. We also note that in a Cournot market with n firms of

equal size (i.e., si* = 1/n), we have 1 2 nL L L L :

* 1/ 10000 / HHI

10000 10000

ii

s n nL L

12

Hence, HHI 10000 L

In the case where firms have different sizes, HHI can be shown to be equal to the product of the price elasticity of

demand and the weighted average of the Lerner indices of the firms, the weights being the market shares (Tirole

[1992]; see also Appendix B):

1

HHI 10000 *

n

i i

i

s L

We summarize the relationships between the Lerner Indices for the monopoly, Cournot oligopoly, and

perfect competition:

Monopoly Cournot Oligopoly Perfect Competition

*1> > 0 is

A practical obstacle to the use of the Lerner index is that it is not easily calculated because it requires knowledge of

either the marginal cost of the firm or the price elasticity of demand, both of which are not readily available.

4. MARKET CONCENTRATION AT THE PHILIPPINE WESM

Calculating measures of concentration in an electricity market can be tricky. The problem lies in the choice

of the capacity measures upon which market shares are calculated. Market shares may be based on registered

capacity (rated capacity), available capacity, offered capacity, or generated capacity. Registered capacity refers to

the rated capacity (quantity of electricity that a generating unit can produce) as declared by its owner when the unit

is registered at WESM. If a trader owns or controls several generating units, then available capacity refers to total

registered capacity less capacity on outage. Offered capacity is the total quantity of electricity offered by a trader

during a trading period. Generated capacity is the quantity of electricity actually produced by a generating unit

during a trading period. In addition to these types of classification, it is important to monitor uncommitted capacity -

the capacity left over after removing bilaterally contracted capacity - because it is the stuff of the spot market.

In calculating measures of concentration at WESM we must first clarify the role of the Power Sector Assets

and Liabilities Management (PSALM) Corporation as a trader in the market. PSALM acquired the National Power

Corporation (NPC) contracts with Independent Power Producers (IPPs) and is, therefore, managing (hence, trading)

the energy outputs of these IPPs. So for all practical purposes, PSALM owns and controls the IPP generators’

outputs8. We shall refer to these IPPs as PSALM IPPs.

8 In fact, PSALM is considered a generation company by Sec. q of the Implementing Rules and Regulations of EPIRA .

13

Table 4 shows the sellers at WESM as of July 21, 2008. A large part (71%) of the capacity registered at

WESM was controlled by the government, represented by PSALM (55%) and NPC (16%). (In fact, under EPIRA,

the generators whose electricity outputs are traded by NPC at WESM are now owned by PSALM.) The remaining

29% of the registered capacity was split among First Gen IPPs (15%), Masinloc Power Partners Corp (5%), SN

Aboitiz Power (4%), Quezon Power (Philippines) Ltd. (4%) and others (1%) (Figure 4). Based on Table 4, HHI =

3549 indicating a highly concentrated market.

Table 4. Registered Capacity Controlled by Sellers at WESM (7/21/2008)

Company Registered Capacity (MW) Share (%) (Share)2

1. PSALM (Power Sector Assets and Liabilities Management) Corp* 6215.8 54.88 3011.81

2. NPC (National Power Corp)** 1785.7 15.76 248.38

3. FIRST GEN IPPs (Excludes BPPC, a PSALM IPP) 1699.3 15.00 225.00

4. MPPC (Masinloc Power Partners Corp) 610.0 5.39 29.05

5. SNAP (SN Aboitiz Power) 480.0 4.24 17.98

6. QPPL (Quezon Power (Philippines) Ltd.) 459.0 4.05 16.40

7. TAPGC (Trans-Asia Power Generation Corp) 50.0 0.44 0.19

8. NORTHWIND 27.0 0.23 0.05

TOTAL 11326.8 100.00 HHI = 3549

*PSALM sells the output of the IPPs with NPC contracts. **Includes Batangas (Calaca) CFTPP (660 MW), Makban GPP (454 MW), and Tiwi GPP (275.7 MW), which were privatized but have not been turned over to the winning bidders.

Source of basic data: MAG-PEMC

Figure 4. Control of Capacity in the Luzon Grid Registered at WESM (7/21/2008)

PSALM55%

NPC16%

FIRSTGEN15%

MPPC5%

SNAP4%

QPPL4%

OTHERS1%

14

4.1. Trading Teams

When WESM started its commercial operations on June 26, 2006, PSALM and NPC controlled about 55%

and 22%, respectively, of the generation capacity registered with WESM making these government agencies the

dominant players in the wholesale market with considerable market power. To mitigate this dominance and enhance

competition, the PSALM IPPs were to be grouped, each group being assigned to an IPP Administrator, an

independent entity to be appointed by PSALM Corporation to manage the energy output of those plants. However,

at the start of WESM commercial operations, these IPP Administrators were not in place, making PSALM an

interim IPP Administrator controlling more than 30% of the installed capacity in the Luzon Grid. This appeared to

go against Paragraph 45(a) of EPIRA which provides that “no company or related group can own, operate or control

more than thirty percent (30%) of the installed generating capacity of a grid and/or twenty-five percent (25%) of the

national installed generating capacity.” But PSALM and NPC are exempt from this provision by virtue of Rule 11,

Sec. 4 of the EPIRA Implementing Rules and Regulations (EPIRA IRR [2002]).

The exemption, however, does not erase the dominance of PSALM and NPC at WESM which goes against

the main objective of EPIRA namely, to promote competition. This is probably the reason why the idea of

independent trading teams within PSALM and NPC that compete with each other had to be devised9. PSALM

initially split its IPPs into four trading teams. NPC outdid PSALM by creating a trading team for each plant and had

nine trading teams at the start of WESM commercial operations. As of July 21, 2008, PSALM had merged its

trading teams into three and NPC gave up four teams to privatization. The trading teams as of July 21, 2008 are

shown in Table 5 which shows an HHI of 1353, indicating a moderately concentrated market.

Table 5. Trading Teams at WESM (7/21/08)

Trading Team Registered Capacity (MW) % Share (Share)2

1. PSALM Trading Team 1 2021.0 17.84 318.26

2. PSALM Trading Team 2 2551.0 22.52 507.15

3. PSALM Trading Team 3 1643.8 14.51 210.54

4. ANGAT HEP (NPC) 246.0 2.17 4.71

5. BINGA HEP (SNAP Benguet) 100.0 0.88 0.77

9 There is some debate about the effectiveness of this set-up because a company’s trading teams that compete with each other and the

company’s management have inherently conflicting objectives. Moreover, as hired traders, it is possible for trading teams to be influenced by the

managers.

15

6. MASINLOC CFTPP (Masinloc Power Partners) 610.0 5.39 29.05

7. BACMAN GPP (NPC) 150.0 1.32 1.74

8. BATANGAS CFTPP (NPC) 660.0 5.83 33.99

9. MAKBAN GPP (NPC) 454.0 4.01 16.08

10. TIWI GPP (NPC) 275.7 2.43 5.90

11. FGHC (First Gas Holdings Corp) 1587.3 14.01 196.28

12. QPPL (Quezon Power Philippines Ltd) 459.0 4.05 16.40

13. MAGAT (SN Aboitiz Power) 380.0 3.35 11.22

14. FGHPC (First Gen Hydro Power Corp) 112.0 0.99 0.98

15. TAPGC (Trans-Asia Power Generation Corp) 50.0 0.44 0.19

16. NORTHWIND 27.0 0.24 0.06

TOTAL 11326.8 100.0 HHI = 1353

Source of basic data: MAG-PEMC

Since the generation market is still concentrated even with three PSALM trading teams, it would be

interesting to find out what the concentration will be if each plant were to be regarded as a trader. Table 6 lists the

plants and their shares of registered capacity and the squares of the shares. It shows an HHI of 623, indicating an

unconcentrated market.

What these results suggest is that market concentration can be reduced if the management of the capacities

of PSALM IPPs can be assigned to as many independent Administrators as possible, certainly more than the three

teams that are currently doing the trading. Otherwise, the generation market will continue to remain concentrated.

Table 6. Trading Teams by Generating Plants

Generating Plant Registered Capacity (MW) % Share (Share)2

1. FGHC - Sta Rita 1054 9.31 86.59

2. FGHC - San Lorenzo 533.3 4.71 22.17

3. FGHPC - Masiway 12.0 0.11 0.01

4. FGHPC - Pantabangan 100.0 0.88 0.78

5. QPPL 459.0 4.05 16.42

6. NORTHWIND 27.0 0.24 0.06

16

7. TAPGC 50.0 0.44 0.19

8. SNAP BENGUET - Binga 100.0 0.88 0.78

9. SNAP - Magat 380.0 3.35 11.26

10. MPPC - Masinloc 610.0 5.39 29.00

11. NPC - Angat 246.0 2.17 4.72

12. NPC - Bacman 150.0 1.32 1.75

13. NPC - Batangas (Calaca) 660.0 5.83 33.95

14. NPC - Makban 454.0 4.01 16.07

15. NPC - Tiwi 275.7 2.43 5.92

16. PSALM-IPP - KEPCO Ilijan 1200.0 10.59 112.24

17. PSALM-IPP - CE Casecnan 165.0 1.46 2.12

18. PSALM-IPP - HEDCOR 30.0 0.26 0.07

19. PSALM-IPP - NIA BALIGATAN 6.0 0.05 0.00

20. PSALM-IPP - Limay 620.0 5.47 29.96

21. PSALM-IPP - Bakun 76.0 0.67 0.45

22. PSALM-IPP - Bauang 225.0 1.99 3.94

23. PSALM-IPP - Sual 1200.0 10.59 112.24

24. PSALM-IPP - Malaya 650.0 5.74 32.93

25. PSALM-IPP - San Roque 400.0 3.53 12.47

26. PSALM-IPP - Pagbilao 763.0 6.74 45.38

27. PSALM-IPP - Subic Power 116.0 1.02 1.05

28. PSALM-IPP - Botocan 20.8 0.18 0.03

29. PSALM-IPP - Caliraya 24.0 0.21 0.04

30. PSALM-IPP - CBK (KPSPP) 720.0 6.36 40.41

HHI = 623

Source of basic data: MAG-PEMC

Although the market may be classified by HHI and Table 3 as unconcentrated, it does not guarantee the

absence of market power. As we showed in an example, pivotal suppliers can exist in unconcentrated electricity

markets under tight supply and demand conditions.

17

5. PIVOTAL SUPPLIERS

Table 7 (see also Figure 5) shows the generating plants that were pivotal suppliers during peak hours in

2007. The Pivotal Supplier Index was calculated using the demand and the offered capacities of the generating

plants for each trading hour. As expected, the larger plants achieved pivotal supplier status more often than smaller

plants. The largest generating plant (KEPCO ILIJAN, 1200 MW) was a pivotal supplier for 53.6% of the peak hours

in 2007. Another large plant (STA RITA, 1054 MW) was a pivotal supplier at 53.8%. Although SUAL is as large as

KEPCO ILIJAN, it was a pivotal supplier for only 29.8% of the peak hours because it was on outage during the first

quarter of 2007.

Table 7. Pivotal Supplier Frequency Index, Peak Hours: 12/26/2006 - 12/25/2007

Generating Plant Trading Company/Team Registered Capacity Pivotal Supplier

Frequency Index MW % Share

1. KEPCO ILIJAN PSALM 1 1200.0 10.59 53.6

2. LIMAY CCGT PSALM 1 620.0 5.47 8.3

3. CE CASECNAN PSALM 1 165.0 1.46 3.8

4. HEDCOR PSALM 1 30.0 0.26 1.9

5. SUAL CFTPP PSALM 2 1200.0 10.59 29.8

6. SAN ROQUE PSALM 2 400.0 3.53 7.4

7. BAUANG DPP PSALM 2 225.0 1.99 6.7

8. BAKUN PSALM 2 76.0 0.67 4.0

9. MALAYA PSALM 2 650.0 5.74 1.4

10. PAGBILAO CFTPP PSALM 3 763.0 6.73 42.1

11. CBK (KPSPP) PSALM 3 720.0 6.36 5.5

12. SUBIC PSALM 3 116.0 1.02 4.1

13. BOTOCAN PSALM 3 20.8 0.18 2.7

14. CALIRAYA PSALM 3 24.0 0.21 3.0

15. STA RITA FGPP FGHC 1054.0 9.31 53.8

16. SAN LORENZO FGPP FGHC 533.3 4.71 31.3

17. MASIWAY FGHPC 12.0 0.11 2.8

18

18. PANTABANGAN FGHPC 100.0 0.88 4.8

19. QPPL QUEZON POWER 459.0 4.05 28.2

20. MAKBAN GPP NPCA 454.0 4.01 21.1

21. TIWI GPP NPCA 275.7 2.43 7.5

22. BATANGAS CFTPP NPCA 660.0 5.83 18.9

23. MASINLOC NPCB 610.0 5.39 19.3

24. ANGAT NPC 246.0 2.17 4.8

25. BACMAN NPC 150.0 1.32 1.2

26. BINGA NPC/SNAPBENGT 100.0 0.88 3.7

27. MAGAT SNAPC 380.0 3.35 11.5

28. TRANS-ASIA TRANS-ASIA 50.0 0.44 2.8

A Privatized but has not been turned over to the winning bidder as of 8/26/08.

B Turned over to Masinloc Partners on 4/16/08.

C Turned over to SNAP on 4/25/07.

Source of basic data: MAG-PEMC

Figure 5. Pivotal Suppliers, Peak Hours: 2007

(psfi = pivotal supplier frequency index; regcap = registered capacity

020

40

60

psfi

0 500 1000 1500regcap

QPPL (28%)

SUAL (30%)

STA RITA (54%) KEPCO ILIJAN (54%)

PAGBILAO (42%)

SAN ROQUE

SAN LORENZO (31%)

CBK

MALAYA

LIMAY

MASINLOC (19%)MAKBAN

MASIWAY (3%)

MAGAT

CALACA (19%)

19

What is worth noting in Figure 5 is that small generators (e.g., MASIWAY, 12 MW) became pivotal

suppliers at certain times during peak hours. This indicates tight demand and supply conditions and confirms the

observation that small suppliers can acquire market power under these conditions (Borenstein [2000]). This raises

the following questions: Why is offered capacity barely enough to meet the demand? Is offered capacity very much

less than available capacity? If so, what is the size of the gap between available capacity and offered capacity?

6. CAPACITY GAPS

We adopt the term “capacity gap” used by WESM to refer to the difference between available capacity and

offered capacity. If a plant has 1000 MW of available capacity and offers only 600 MW to the market, then the

capacity gap is 400 MW. This is an important issue in wholesale electricity markets because capacity withholding,

as shown by the example in Section 3.1, can be used to reduce supply and raise the price of electricity. In fact,

empirical evidence of this behavior exists. For example, Wolak and Patrick [1997] provide evidence that capacity

withholding by the two dominant generators in the England and Wales market resulted in price increases. Joskow

and Kahn [2001] find evidence that withholding of capacity to drive up price occurred in the California market

during Summer 2000.

As a first cut in the analysis of capacity gaps, we look at the ratio of offered capacity to registered capacity.

Table 8 presents the average monthly offered capacity as a percentage of registered capacity for 2007 and shows that

average offered capacity was less than 50% of registered capacity throughout most of the year.

Table 8. Monthly Average Offered and Registered Capacity: 2007

Month Average Registered Capacity (MW)

Average Offered Capacity (MW)

Offered Capacity/Registered Capacity (%)

January 11746 5211 44

February 11759 5333 45

March 11722 5293 45

April 11657 5230 45

May 11664 5692 49

June 11673 5565 48

July 11676 5022 43

August 11637 5618 48

September 11551 5501 48

October 11555 5668 49

20

November 11502 5739 50

December 11491 5453 47

Source: MAG-PEMC

PEMC made some estimates of available capacity by subtracting scheduled and forced outages from

registered capacity. Table 9 shows monthly estimates of the capacity gaps for the year 2007. Capacity gap ranged

from 3,467 MW to 4,241 MW with an annual average of 3,914 MW. This is graphically shown in Figure 6, which

also confirms that offered capacity is indeed close to demand. In view of this large capacity gap, it is fair to ask if

there had been capacity withholding in the wholesale spot market in 2007.

Table 9. Monthly Average Capacity Gap: 2007

Month Available Capacity (MW) Offered Capacity (MW) Capacity Gap (MW)

January 9153 5211 3942

February 9134 5333 3801

March 9284 5293 3991

April 9085 5230 3855

May 9934 5692 4241

June 9675 5565 4110

July 9009 5022 3987

August 9820 5618 4202

September 9449 5501 3948

October 9135 5668 3467

November 9254 5739 3515

December 9365 5453 3913

Average 9358 5444 3914

Source: MAG-PEMC

21

Figure 6. Registered Capacity, Available Capacity, Offered Capacity, and Demand: 2007

(Monthly Average)

7. CONCENTRATION IN THE SPOT MARKET

When a portion of a generation supplier’s electricity is contracted, the supplier’s share in the spot market is

reduced. Only the uncommitted capacity will compete for the demand left unfilled by bilateral contracts. If a large

portion of generation is contracted, the uncommitted capacity may tend to be concentrated in a few sellers. It is,

therefore, important to examine the concentration of uncommitted capacity.

First, we look at the spot market share since WESM started commercial operations. Figure 7 shows the

monthly split (in percent) between the amount of electricity sold through the spot market and those sold through

bilateral contracts during the first 24 months of WESM operations. Approximately 56% of the of the pool purchases

were made through bilateral contracts during the first month (July 2006) of WESM operations (see Table 10).

Within six months the share of bilateral contracts rose to 83% and by the end of 2007 the share further increased to

88%, where it hovered up to June 2008.

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

12000

14000

Ja

n

Fe

b

Ma

r

Ap

r

Ma

y

Ju

n

Ju

l

Aug

Se

p

Oct

No

v

De

c

MW

Registered Capacity Available Capacity

Offered Capacity Demand

22

Figure 7. Spot Market vs Bilateral Contracts Market: Monthly Shares

Table 10. Spot vs Bilateral Contracts

Month Spot Market Share (%) Bilateral Contracts Share (%)

2006 July 44 56

August 37 63

September 39 61

October 43 57

November 33 67

December 17 83

2007 January 19 81

February 16 84

March 18 82

April 21 79

May 15 85

June 23 77

July 16 84

August 14 86

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

2006 July 2007 January

July 2008 January

Perc

en

t

Spot Bilateral Contracts

23

September 11 89

October 8 92

November 11 89

December 12 88

2008 January 13 87

February 14 86

March 12 88

April 17 83

May 11 89

June* 12* 88*

*Preliminary

Source: MO-PEMC

7.1. Shares in the Spot Market

Figure 8 shows the spot market shares by companies for the year 2007. The data are based on actual

generation. PSALM dominated the spot market accounting for 83% of actual generation. The HHI is 6894 (see

Table 11A).

Figure 8. Spot Market Shares: 2007

PSALM82.5%

SNAP7.0%

NPC4.5%

FIRST GEN3.4%

MPPC1.3%

OTHERS1.3%

24

Table 11A. Spot Market Shares: 2007

Company Share (%) (Share)2

PSALM 82.53 6811.20

NPC 4.45 19.80

FIRST GEN IPPs 3.43 11.76

MPPC 1.33 1.77

SNAP 6.99 48.86

QPPL 0.46 0.21

TAPGC 0.59 0.35

NORTHWIND 0.01 0.00

WESMTMP 0.22 0.05

TOTAL 100.00 HHI = 6894

Source of basic data: MAG-PEMC Table 11B shows the spot market shares of the trading teams for the year 2007. One notices at once that the

top three are the PSALM trading teams which account for 83% of the spot market. The spot market is still highly

concentrated with an HHI of 2357.

Table 11B. Spot Market Shares of Trading Teams at WESM: 2007

Trading Team Share (%) (Share)2

1. PSALM Trading Team 1 35.81 1282.36

2. PSALM Trading Team 2 17.92 321.13

3. PSALM Trading Team 3 26.15 683.82

4. PSALM Trading Team 4 2.65 7.02

5. ANGAT HEP (NPC) 0.48 0.23

6. BINGA HEP (SNAP Benguet) 0.37 0.14

7. MASINLOC CFTPP (Masinloc Power Partners) 1.33 1.77

8. BACMAN GPP (NPC) 0.12 0.01

9. BATANGAS CFTPP (NPC) 1.46 2.13

10. MAKBAN GPP (NPC) 1.34 1.80

25

11. TIWI GPP (NPC) 0.85 0.72

12. FGHC (First Gas Holdings Corp) 0.57 0.32

13. QPPL (Quezon Power Philippines Ltd) 0.46 0.21

14. MAGAT-NPC (Jan-Apr 08; became MAGAT-SNAP)

MAGAT (SN Aboitiz Power)

0.20

6.62

46.51

15. FGHPC (First Gen Hydro Power Corp) 2.86 8.18

16. TAPGC (Trans-Asia Power Generation Corp) 0.59 0.35

17. NORTHWIND 0.01 0.00

TOTAL HHI = 2357

Source of basic data: MAG-PEMC

8. SUMMARY AND CONCLUDING REMARKS

Market power in the restructured and liberalized electricity industry is of great concern because its abuse

can negate the potential gains from competition. The experiences of liberalized electricity markets (think California)

show that market power had been exercised and had been costly to the consumers. This means that market power

has to be closely monitored, especially during the period of transition from regulation to liberalization.

Monitoring market power has traditionally relied on concentration indices based on market shares such as

the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI). However, HHI is a market-wide index which, therefore, does not identify

specific firms. In contrast, the pivotal supplier index identifies the firms that possess market power at every trading

period.

The Philippine electricity market is in a period of transition as the restructuring provisions of the Electric

Power Industry Reform Act of 2001 are being implemented. Under current market structure, the HHI indicates a

highly concentrated market. The device of trading teams introduced by the government companies has diminished

the concentration but the market is still concentrated. In addition, the independence of trading teams belonging to the

same company may not be sustained as the purpose of competing teams (lowering the price) run into conflict with

the objective of management (increasing revenues).

The pivotal supplier data show that in 2007 many plants, including small ones, became pivotal suppliers

during peak hours, creating opportunities for the exercise of market power. (Another interesting empirical question

is whether or not market power had been exercised unilaterally by a trader.) This is a consequence of a tight supply

26

(offered capacity) and demand condition. In 2007 average offered capacity was only 47% of average registered

capacity. PEMC estimates of unoffered capacity (available capacity less offered capacity) averaged 3,914 MW for

2007. (Another interesting empirical question is whether or not this large unoffered capacity affected the price

outcomes).

PSALM, through no fault of its own, is the dominant player in the wholesale market. This dominance

became pronounced when more generators shifted to bilateral contracts leaving the PSALM-IPPs with the bulk of

uncommitted capacity that competed in the spot market. In 2007 the generators controlled by PSALM accounted for

83% of actual generation in the spot market, making the spot market highly concentrated. This highlights the

importance and urgency of the dominance mitigation provision of EPIRA: appointing independent IPP

Administrators. The good news is that bidding for IPP Administrators (IPPAs) has started; the first one was held on

June 26, 2009. Although this bidding failed because the bids fell short of the reserve price, PSALM successfully

conducted a second round of bidding on August 28, 2009 for the appointment of IPPAs to manage the contracted

capacities of two coal-fired plants which account for roughly a third of the IPP contracts for Luzon and Visayas.

27

Appendix A

The Lerner Index under Cournot Competition

Suppose that there are n firms that are maximizing their profits by choosing quantities of output. Let

Qi = output of firm i

Q = Q1 + ··· + Qi + ··· + Qn

P(Q) = the industry demand function

Ci(Qi) = cost function of firm i

The profit of firm i is given by

( ) ( )i i i iP Q Q C Q

The first-order condition for maximum profit of firm i is

( )(1) 0i

i

i i

CdP Q iP QdQ Q QQ i

Rearranging terms,

(since 1)dP Q

P MC Qi idQ Qi

*1

*P MC Q sQ dPi i isi dQPP Q P dQ

Q dP

Hence,

*i

i

sL

where is the price elasticity of demand.

28

Appendix B

The Relationship between HHI and the Lerner Index in a Cournot Market

We show that, in a Cournot market, HHI is related to the price elasticity of demand and the Lerner indices

of the firms. We begin with the Lerner index:

*i

i

sL

*i is L

Multiplying both sides of the equation by si*, we get

2

* *( )i i is s L

Taking the sum over i = 1, 2, ..., n, we have

2

1 1

( *) *

n n

i i i

i i

s s L

Note that si = market share in percent, i.e., si = 100si*. Hence,

2

1 1

2

1 1

1

*10000

10000 *

HHI 10000 *

n ni

i i

i i

n n

i i i

i i

n

i i

i

ss L

s s L

s L

Thus HHI depends on the price elasticity of demand and the weighted average of the firms’ Lerner indices, the

weights being the market shares.

29

References

Borentstein, Severin. 2000. Understanding Competitive Pricing and Market Power in the Wholesale Electricity

Markets. Electricity Journal. July 13:6, pp. 49-57

Borenstein, Severin. 2002. The Trouble With Electricity Markets: Understanding California’s Restructuring

Disaster. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 16 (Winter 2002)

Borenstein, Severin, James B. Bushnell, and Christopher R. Knittel. 1999. Market Power in Electricity Markets:

Beyond Concentration Measures, Working Paper PWP-059r, Program on Workable Energy Regulation (POWER),

University of California Energy Institute, Berkeley, California (Feb 1999)

Bushnell, J., Knittel, C., and Wolak, F. (1999) “Estimating the Opportunities for Market Power in a Deregulated

Wisconsin Electricity Market”, The Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 47, September 1999

EPIRA. 2001. Electric Power Industry Reform Act of 2001

EPIRA IRR. 2002. Electric Power Industry Reform Act of 2001, Implementing Rules and Regulations

FERC. 2004. 107 FERC 61,018. Docket No. ER96-2495-016, et al.

Joskow, P. and Kahn, E. 2001. A Quantitative Analysis of Pricing Behavior in California’s Wholesale Electricity

Market During Summer 2000. NBER Working Paper 8157, http://www.nber.org/papers/w8157

MAG-PEMC, Annual Market Assessment Report for 2007. Market Assessment Group, Philippine Electricity

Market Corporation, Mandaluyong City

NSO. 2007. 2005 Annual Survey of Philippine Business and Industry, National Statistics Office, Manila

NSCB. 2008. Philippine Statistical Yearbook, National Statistical Coordination Board, Makati

Tirole, Jean. 1992. The Theory of Industrial Organization, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.

WESM. 2002. Wholesale Electricity Spot Market Rules, Mandaluyong City

30

Wolak, Frank. 2000. “Lessons from International Experience with Electricity Market Monitoring”, Center for the

Study of Energy Markets (CSEM) WP 134, University of California Energy Institute, 2547 Channing Way,

Berkeley, California 94720-5180, www.ucei.org

Wolak, F. A. and Patrick, R. H. 1997. The Impact of Market Rules and Market Structure on the Price Determination

Process in the England and Wales Electricity Market. POWER Working Paper PWP-047, University of California

Energy Institute, Berkeley, California