19
10.4.2017 e.Proofing http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 1/19 Valuing the Tax Shield under Asymmetric Taxation Lutz Kruschwitz, Andreas Löffler, Phone +491632542508 Email [email protected] Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaft, Freie Universität Berlin, Boltzmannstraße 20, 14195 Berlin, Deutschland Abstract Models on enterprise valuation show that the effective or marginal tax rate (ETR) increases linearly with the debt ratio, implying that tax benefits from debt are very important. Empirical research has repeatedly emphasized that this result cannot be sustained, and that tax benefits are in reality much less relevant to valuation. It is an open question whether this impression can also be maintained within a theoretical model. All theoretical models so far assume that the tax rate is constant and identical for gains and losses. In this paper, we attempt to analytically determine the value of a tax shield assuming that gains and losses are taxed differently. We want to precisely determine the impact of a nonconstant tax rate on the value of the tax shield. Previous research could only integrate this asymmetry by employing empirical methods and simulation studies, as an analytical solution had not yet been presented. Looking at a very popular financing policy we are able to present a closed form solution for the effective tax rate. Our results reveal that this value, instead of being a linear function of the debt ratio, is rather concave, sustaining repeated empirical observations. However, our results also show that the “power” or “strength” of this concavity is not enough to explain the empirical results concerning the impact of the tax shield. Therefore, adding an asymmetric taxation is not enough to determine the empirically observed puzzle of tax shield valuation. Keywords 1 1,* 1

V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 1/19

Valuing the Tax Shield underAsymmetric TaxationLutz Kruschwitz,

Andreas Löffler,

Phone +49­163­2542508Email [email protected]

Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaft, Freie Universität Berlin,Boltzmannstraße 20, 14195 Berlin, Deutschland

Abstract

Models on enterprise valuation show that the effective or marginal tax rate(ETR) increases linearly with the debt ratio, implying that tax benefits fromdebt are very important. Empirical research has repeatedly emphasized thatthis result cannot be sustained, and that tax benefits are in reality much lessrelevant to valuation. It is an open question whether this impression can alsobe maintained within a theoretical model.

All theoretical models so far assume that the tax rate is constant and identicalfor gains and losses. In this paper, we attempt to analytically determine thevalue of a tax shield assuming that gains and losses are taxed differently. Wewant to precisely determine the impact of a non­constant tax rate on the valueof the tax shield. Previous research could only integrate this asymmetry byemploying empirical methods and simulation studies, as an analytical solutionhad not yet been presented.

Looking at a very popular financing policy we are able to present a closed­form solution for the effective tax rate. Our results reveal that this value,instead of being a linear function of the debt ratio, is rather concave,sustaining repeated empirical observations. However, our results also showthat the “power” or “strength” of this concavity is not enough to explain theempirical results concerning the impact of the tax shield. Therefore, adding anasymmetric taxation is not enough to determine the empirically observedpuzzle of tax shield valuation.

Keywords

1

1,*

1

Page 2: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 2/19

JEL-Classification

1. IntroductionHow important are the tax benefits from debt? Using formal models, thisquestion was raised and answered as early as Modigliani and Miller ( 1963 )using a very simple financing policy (constant debt). Later Miles and Ezzell( 1980 ) were able to give a closed­form solution for another financing policy(constant leverage ratio) that remains one of the most popular assumptions infinance today. Then, research moved to empirical and simulation studies.AQ1

The literature has in particular looked at the ratio of tax shield value andenterprise value of a levered firm to epitomize the influence of a corporate tax onfirm value. This ratio sometimes is called “marginal tax rate” (also MTR) in theempirical literature. Using this term in our model would be rather confusing,given that the tax shield is a tax benefit and given that we analyze the entire taxbenefit and not a marginal surplus. To be precise, we will analyze a coefficientthat measures the present value of all future tax shields relative to the presentvalue of all the future income, given that the company is levered (see Eq. 4below). Hence, we will denote it as “effective tax shield ratio” ETR.

Looking at the theoretical results above, we identify a common element. InModigliani­Miller’s as well as Miles–Ezzell’s case the ETR is linear in today’sdebt ratio (see below). If we use the concept of elasticity the immediate result isthat the tax benefit has an elasticity of one with respect to the debt ratio. Thisimplies that taxes are very important when valuing companies and such resultsshould be empirically observed, in particular when tax rates are changing.

And this is where the issue gets interesting. Many papers have repeatedly arguedthat the effect of debt on the value of the tax shield is much less than boththeories – Modigliani­Miller or Miles–Ezzell – predict. Myers et al. ( 1998 ) haveargued that taxes are of third­order importance in the hierarchy of corporatedecisions, hence much less than the model’s presage.

Many reasons can be mentioned (financial flexibility, use of non­debt tax shields,pecking­order theory, target ratings of rating agencies, costs of financialdistress), but one idea immediately comes to mind: Until now, in any analyticalmodel where corporate taxes are introduced, gains and losses are treated

Page 3: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 3/19

symmetrically. But the treatment of gains and losses differs considerably acrossnational tax code regulations and is usually not symmetric. Many countries grantloss carry­back and offer schemes for loss carry­forward. These accumulatedtax losses can be quite enormous, as Sarkar ( 2014 ) has emphasized. Losses andnon­deducted interest can be restricted by the amount of tax­deductible losses toa certain proportion of current­year profits or may be ultimately lost because asubstantial amount of shares of a loss making firm is transferred to a newowner.

If, for example, losses cannot be imputed at all but gains are subject to tax thiswill have an impact on the value of the tax shield and hence also the elasticity.We would expect that the influence is of an order less than one. Up to now thisresult could only be verified using simulation models or empirical studies;particularly worth mentioning are Shevlin ( 1990 ), Graham (1996a , 1996b ,2000 , 2003 , 2006 ), Graham and Mills ( 2008 ), Graham and Kim (2009 ), Blouinet al. ( 2010 ). The effect of a different taxation of gains and losses (so­called “taxconvexity”) has been analyzed, for example, in Sarkar ( 2008 ) using acontinuous­time setup. Sarkar was only able to simulate first results. Koch(2013 , Part E) thoroughly discussed the weaknesses of such simulation studiesand why we cannot relay on simulations alone: Koch shows that the estimationof marginal tax rates using a random walk approach involves a hugemeasurement error. With simulations, one must rely on few numerical values todeduce structural statements for all possible numbers.

This is the point where our paper continues. Our aim is to present an analyticalmodel where gains are taxed differently than losses, in one case even presentinga closed­form solution for the value of the tax shield. Our approach clearlyshows that the elasticity of the ETR with respect to the debt ratio is less than one,pointing in the right direction. In our examples, the value of the tax shield turnsout to be a concave function of the leverage ratio.

We have already mentioned the consensus that the value of the tax shield is ofless importance for corporate decisions. It will turn out that theoretical resultswill support this concord. Although the ETR is not linear in the debt ratio,substantially lowering the tax shield compared to the symmetric case turns out tobe challenging. For this to be the case rather unrealistic assumptions arerequired: For example, the cost of capital would have to be very far away fromthe riskless rate. In the end, our paper shows that (as in the empirical andsimulation literature) formal models so far cannot provide a convincing answerwhy tax shields are so low.

2. Assumptions

1

2

3

Page 4: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 4/19

1(1)

2(2)

3(3)

We assume a market with the usual properties. There is a risk­free asset withinterest rate which, for simplicity, is assumed to be constant over time. Themarket is free of arbitrage and hence there is a risk­neutral probability measure such that any claim can be evaluated using the discounted ­expected cash flowof that claim.

The firm we want to consider has unlevered pre­tax cash flows that areauto­regressive,

for all . The random variables are assumed to be independent andidentically distributed (iid), with the expectation of zero and satisfy .

Given these assumptions, the price of an unlevered (post­tax) cash flowstream ( ) with a tax rate is given by the sum of its ­expected and discounted value:

is a firm income tax rate, cash flows (instead of accounting incomes) aresubject to taxation. We ignore personal income taxes in order to keep our modeltractable.

The unlevered company has after­tax cash flows of . The leveredcompany can deduct taxes if there are no losses. Hence, its after­tax cash flow is

This gives a tax shield at time of

In our analysis we observe cases where the cash flows can take values smallerthan the required interest payments, which would usually mean a default of the

rf

Q

Q4

CFut

= (1 + )CFut CFu

t−1 εt

t > 0 5εt

> −1εt

V ut

CFus s = t + 1,… τ Q

= .V u0 ∑

t=1

∞[(1 − τ) ⋅ ]EQ CFu

t

(1 + rf )t

τ

6

(1 − τ)CFut

7

C = − τ( − .F lt CFu

t CFut rfDt−1)

+

t

T :St = − τ( − − (1 − τ)CFut CFu

t rfDt−1)+

CFut

= τrfDt−1

τCFut

if >CFut rfDt−1

else.

= τ min( , ).CFut rfDt−1

Page 5: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 5/19

corporation. In order to be able to work with such cash flows we follow theassumptions in Kruschwitz and Löffler ( 2006 , Chap. 2.2.4). There, it is shownthat default (under very mild assumptions) does not change the valuationequations.

Lastly, we assume that the capital costs of the unlevered firm are constant overtime. From this, for the unlevered company we immediately obtain

Introducing debt, the now levered company will use an amount of debt at time .An equation applies to the valuation of this company, which is quite similar toEq. ( 2 ). However, its value will be determined by the cash flows of thelevered firm. Before we focus on two different types of financing policies thatplay an important role in the theory of business valuation a general result isalmost self­evident: The value of today’s tax shield is concave given any futuredebt level . This result will now be amplified using the following twofinancing policies:

Fixed leverage ratios

Fixed leverage ratios: The first financing policy ischaracterized by the fact that company managementfixes deterministic leverage ratios for the future. Thisis well known in the literature as it is the prerequisitefor using WACC in firm valuation, see Miles and Ezzell( 1980 , p. 722). Because the future values of theindebted firm are stochastic, the same applies for thefuture amounts of debt, . For simplicity,assume that the future leverage ratio is constant overtime, .

Fixed amounts of debt

Fixed amounts of debt: The second financing policy hasmanagement fixing the future amounts of debt, ,deterministically. For convenience, assume that thisamount remains constant over time, .Modigliani and Miller ( 1963 ) discussed this type ofpolicy. As the future values of the indebted firm arestochastic, then the future debt ratios of the firm mustalso be stochastic under this financing policy,

.

8

= .V ut

(1 − τ) CFut

k

t

V l0

Dt9

lt

V lt

=lt Vlt Dt

= (∀t > 0)lt l0

Dt

= (∀t > 0)Dt D0

= /lt D0 V lt

Page 6: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 6/19

4(4)

5(5)

ETR is finally being defined by

We have already mentioned that different definitions have been suggested in theliterature to capture the effect of asymmetric taxation. Shevlin ( 1990 ) as well asGraham (2003 ) consider a “corporate marginal tax rate … defined as the changein the present value of the cash flow paid to (or recovered from) the taxauthorities as a result of earning one extra dollar of TI [tax income] in thecurrent period” (see Shevlin 1990 , p. 1). Analogously, Graham and Kim (2009 )write that the “ETR [marginal tax] rate measures the present value taxconsequences of earning an extra dollar of income today” (p. 416). As can beseen our definition is in line with these descriptions.

We are interested in closed­form solutions for the ETR, particularly if gains andlosses are taxed differently.

3. Main Results

3.1. Financing Policy with Constant Leverage RatiosFirst assume that firm management follows a financing policy with adeterministic and constant leverage ratio, . This case wasaddressed by Miles and Ezzell ( 1980 ). The result is

where is the cost of capital of the unlevered company. It is straightforward todetermine the ETR if gains and losses are taxed symmetrically:

The derivation of a closed­form equation for the ETR under asymmetric taxationis harder. Assume that losses cannot be imputed at all. Let WACC represent theweighted average cost of capital and for some . Weget the following result.

Proposition 1 (Asymmetric Taxation of Gains and Losses) If gains are

ETR := 1 − .V u

0

V l0

= = … = ll0 l1

(1 − τ l) = ,1 + k

1 + rf

rf

kV l

0 V u0

k

= τ l.ETRsymmetric

1 + k

1 + rf

rf

k

WACC = (1 − τ) /CFut V

lt t

10

Page 7: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 7/19

6(6)

Proposition 1 (Asymmetric Taxation of Gains and Losses) If gains aretaxed, while losses are not, then WACC is not stochastic and even constant.Furthermore,

where is a monotonically decreasing function with values between and .

Comparing equations ( 5 ) and ( 6 ) with each other reveals an interesting fact. TheETR differ from each other only by the factor of and

must hold.

Consider an example. Assume that regarding is uniformly distributed onthe interval ; calculating the function for this case yields

Fig. 1 shows the functional relationship between the ETR and the leverage ratio,its main influencing factor. It is easy to see that ETR under symmetrical taxationis a linear function of the debt ratio, while it is a concave function underasymmetric taxation.

Fig. 1

ETR under constant leverage ratios ( , , ) with regarding being uniformly distributed on . The dotted line gives theETR when gains and losses are taxed symmetrically, the straight lines shows theETR if losses cannot be imputed

Nevertheless, we motivated our approach with the empirical observation that thevalue of the tax shields does not seem to be very important when valuingcompanies. Introducing asymmetric taxation does not provide a conclusive

= τ l f ( ) ,ETRasymmetric

1 + k

1 + rf

rf

k

l (1 − τ)rf

WACC

f (⋅) 0

1

f ( )l (1−τ)rf

WACC

0 ≤ f ( ) ≤ 1l (1−τ)rf

WACC

εt Q

[−1, 1] f (⋅) 11

f (x) = 1 − , x ∈ (0, 1].x

4

k = 6 % = 5 %rf τ = 30 % εt

Q [−1, 1]

Page 8: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 8/19

answer to that puzzle. Even our example shows that producing significantlysmaller tax shield with asymmetric taxation compared to the symmetric casecomes at the cost of unrealistic assumptions. If, in our example, the cost ofcapital is increased to a reasonable level results.This example supports the claim that also in a theoretical model an asymmetrictaxation is not the sufficient answer why taxes are of less importance incorporate decisions.

The example already shows that asymmetric taxation hardly explains why“typical conditions” usually result in a rather small tax shield. Looking at theargument of the function carefully proves to be helpful. It can easily be seenthat turns out to be quite a small number and for small the function

approaches . This result can formally be stated as follows:

Proposition 2 If

applies, then , and asymmetric taxation cannot affect the

value of the tax shield.

If the growth rate of cash flows is not negative the right hand side approachesone. With negative rates it may be less than that. But it should not decrease toomuch under normal conditions. On the left hand, however, we have an expressionwhich, under ordinary circumstances, is clearly less than one and often verysmall. Hence, Proposition 2 will regularly hold.

3.2. Financing Policy with Constant Amounts of DebtNow assume that the firm follows a financing policy with deterministic andconstant amounts of debt, . The future values of the leveredfirm are stochastic. Hence, due to the future leverage ratios arestochastic as well. By contrast, the previous leverage ratio was a number at anyfuture time .

Under symmetric taxation the value of the levered firm at each time is

From this, immediately

k ≈ETRasymmetric ETRsymmetric

f (⋅)l (1−τ)rf

WACCx

f (x) 1 12

l (1 − τ) ≤rf

WACCinft

CFut+1

CFut

f ( ) = 1l (1−τ)rf

WACC

13

= = … = DD0 D1

:= D/lt V lt

t

= + τD ,V lt V u

t

−l

Page 9: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 9/19

7(7)

These terms are stochastic for any . Only the current ETR (i.e., at )is deterministic. Under symmetric taxation of gains and losses the ETR at time

is deterministic and is described as

The result is different if gains and losses are taxed differently.

Proposition 3 (Asymmetric Taxation of Gains and Losses) If gains aretaxed, while losses are not imputed at all, then the ETR at time isdeterministic. Depending on the debt, ETR attains a value between and

; the greater the amount of debt, the greater the ETR.

The first value materializes if is sufficiently small. The second value results if . Unfortunately, we do not arrive at a closed­form solution forthe ETR if yields results that are located between and .

Asymmetric taxation is, of course, without any meaning if holds.Obviously, symmetric and asymmetric taxation result in the same tax shields.

Consider an example. The cash flows of the company follow a binomial tree asshown in Fig. 2 , with the initial value and the growth factors and . The cost of capital is given by , the risk­free rate is

, and the tax rate is . Then the risk­neutral probabilities can bedetermined using option pricing theory.

Fig. 2

Binomial tree of cash flows in the second example

= = τ .−V l

t V ut

V lt

τD

V lt

lt

t > 0 t = 0

t = 0

= τ .ETRsymmetric l0

14

t = 0

τl0τ

1+τ

τl0 D τ

1+τ

≥l01

1+τ

D τl0τ

1+τ

≥CFut rfDt

15

C = 1Fu0 u = 1.0

d = 0.9 k = 5%

= 3%rf τ = 60%16

Page 10: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 10/19

Calculating the ETR as a function of today’s leverage ratio gives the resultshown in Fig. 3 . It is clear that beyond a certain amount of debt the ETR nolonger increases, because the resulting losses can no longer be offset againsttaxes. Again we see that ETR is a concave function of debt under asymmetrictaxation and a linear function under symmetric taxation. This agrees withempirical results.

Fig. 3

ETR under constant amounts of debt ( , , , ), when cash flows follow a binomial tree as in figureFig. 2 with and

. The dotted line gives the ETR when gains and losses are taxedsymmetrically, the straight lines shows the ETR if losses cannot be imputed

4. ConclusionEvaluating a firm requires a lot of information, including the value of the firm’sETR. In the past 25 years, there have been articles on the estimation of ETR

l0

k = 5 % = 3 %rf τ = 60 % = 1CFu0

u = 1.0

d = 0.9

Page 11: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 11/19

under asymmetric taxation (gains are taxed, losses are tax­free), but all paperspublished so far work with empirical methods and simulation studies. This paperis the first to attempt an analytical determination of the ETR and our findings fortwo popular financing policies are summarized in Table 1 .

Table 1

Effective tax shield ratio ETR under symmetric and asymmetric taxationAQ2

Financing policy Losses are taxed Losses cannot be imputed

Fixed leverage ratios

Fixed amounts of debt

Empirical studies that recognize a different tax treatment of gains and lossesindicate that taxes are less important in firm evaluation than previously impliedby theoretical papers. Although in our examples the differences between thesymmetric and the asymmetric tax shield valuation can be substantial, with aconstant leverage ratio in realistic cases these differences turn out to be low. Andwe assumed that losses and non­deducted interest are ultimately lost and can becarried neither forward nor backward – in the latter case timing effects come intoplay that will reduce the differences further. Our paper supports the claim thatasymmetric taxation is not the major reason why taxes are of less importance inbusiness decisions at least in the case of a constant debt ratio. This has not beenshown in analytical models so far.

AcknowledgementsWe thank all participants of the 78. VHB­Pfingsttagung 2016 in Munich (withspecial thanks to the two referees) and of the XVII. GEABA­symposium in Basel(as well as Dominica Canefield, Andreas Scholze, Stefan Wielenberg, UlrichSchäfer, and the referees of this journal) for their helpful discussion.

5. Appendix

5.1. Proof of Proposition 1From Eq. ( 3 ), using Eq. ( 2 ), the value of the levered company is

τl1+k

1+rf

rf

kτl f ( )1+k

1+rf

rf

k

l (1−τ)rf

WACC

τl0 τ →l0τ

1+τ

V lt = ∑

s=t+1

∞ [(1 − τ) + τ min( , l )| ]EQ CFus CFu

s rf Vls−1 t

(1 + rf )s−t

Page 12: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 12/19

A1(A1)

A2(A2)

10(A3)

11(A4)

or by employing the stochastic and time­dependent variable

It follows from Kruschwitz and Löffler ( 2015 ), Proposition 2(2015, Proposition2) that there must be a unique solution. However, it is not obvious how todetermine that solution. Claiming that

is deterministic and constant will prove to be correct. From our first assumptionwe get

for an iid variable . Using Eq. (A2 ), insertion yields

The random variables

and

are independent of each other. Under this condition, the expectation of theproduct equals the product of the expectations. Hence using

yields

:=WACC s

(1 − τ)CFus

V ls

V lt = ∑

s=t+1

∞ [(1 − τ) + τ min( , )| ]EQ CFus CFu

s

l (1−τ)rf

WACCs−1CFu

s−1 t

(1 + rf )s−t

WACC =(1 − τ)CFu

s

V ls

= (1 + )CFus CFu

s−1 εs

εs

V lt = +V u

t ∑∞

s=t+1

[τ min( (1+ ), ) ]EQ CFus−1 εs

l (1−τ)rf

WACCCFu

s−1

∣∣∣ t

(1+rf )s−t

= + τ .V ut ∑∞

s=t+1

[ min(1+ , ) ]EQ CFus−1 εs

l (1−τ)rf

WACC

∣∣∣ t

(1+rf )s−t

= (1 + )(1 + )⋯ (1 + )CFus−1 CFu

0 ε1 ε2 εs−1

min(1 + , )εs

l (1 − τ)rf

WACC

x := ( l (1 − τ))/WACCrf

[ ] [ ( ) ]l (1−τ)f

Page 13: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 13/19

12(A5)

We now focus on a function

for . This function is dependent on three terms, namely , the information , and the random variable . The latter being iid, this is an unconditional

expectation that depends only on . Therefore

must hold. Now it can easily be shown that when is small,

because , and when is large

The function is monotonically decreasing with .

We can now determine the tax shield using the newly defined function . Inserting the term into Eq. ( 11A4) yields

This is a closed­form equation for the tax shield.

This result is based on the mere assumption of WACC being deterministic andconstant. If we can trust this result, our assumption was justified. We have to

V lt = + τV u

t ∑∞

s=t+1

[ | ] [min(1+ , )| ]EQ CFus−1 t EQ εs

l (1−τ)rf

WACCt

(1+rf )s−t

= + τ .V ut ∑∞

s=t+1

lrf

WACC

[(1−τ) | ] [min( ,1)| ]EQ CFus−1 t EQ

1+εs

xt

(1+rf )s−t

f (x) [min ( , 1) | ] , t > s=Def EQ

1 + εt

xs

x > 0 x

s εt

x

f (x) = [min ( , 1)]EQ

1 + εt

x

x

f (x) = [min ( , 1)] = 1 ,limx→0

EQ limx→0

1 + εt

x

> −1εt x

f (x) = [min ( , 1)] = 0 .limx→∞

EQ limx→∞

1 + εt

x

x

f ( ) = 1l (1−τ)rf

WACC

V lt = + τV u

t

lrf

WACC∑∞

s=t+1

[(1−τ) | ] [min( ,1)]EQ CFus−1 t EQ

(1+ ) WACCεs

l (1−τ)rf

(1+rf )s−t

= + τ f ( )V ut

lrf

WACC

l (1−τ)rf

WACC∑∞

s=t+1

[(1−τ) | ]EQ CFus−1 t

(1+rf )s−t

= + τ f ( ) .V ut

lrf

WACC

l (1−τ)rf

WACC

(1−τ) +CFut V u

t

1+rf

Page 14: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 14/19

show that if there is a constant and deterministic WACC, there is a uniquesolution. To this end, insert the capital costs equations into Eq. ( 12A5):

This can easily be transformed to

This corresponds to the adjustment formula of Miles and Ezzell ( 1980 ) exceptfor the term .

To assure ourselves that a unique solution exists for WACC, consider two cases.For the left­hand side (LHS) of the equation goes to zero, while theright­hand side (RHS) goes to . So the RHS is larger than the LHS.Assuming, however, that , the LHS goes beyond all limits and ispositive, while the RHS remains finite. Because of the monotonicity of thefunction there can be only one unique solution for . The ETR results easilyfrom Eq. ( 12A5):

This completes the proof.

5.2. The example with constant leverage ratio and proof ofProposition 2The function from

can be determined if is regarding uniformly distributed on . Then

We have, since

= + τ f ( ) (1 + ) (1 − τ)(1 − τ) CFu

t

WACC

(1 − τ) CFut

k

lrf

WACC (1 + )rf

l (1 − τ)rf

WACC

1

kCF

WACC = k − τ l f ( ) .1 + k

1 + rfrf

l (1 − τ)rf

WACC

f (⋅)

WACC → 0

k > 0

WACC → ∞

f (⋅)

ETRasymmetric= 1 − = 1 −

CFut

k

CFut

WACC

WACC

k

= τ l f ( ) .1 + k

1 + rf

rf

k

l (1 − τ)rf

WACC

f (⋅)

f (x) = [min ( , 1)] ,EQ

1 + εt

x

ε Q [−a, a]

f (x) = min ( , 1) dε .∫a

−a

1 + ε

x

1

2a

x > 0

1 + ε

Page 15: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 15/19

Distinguish two cases. First, if then the integral is given by

The second case corresponds to . Then, the integral is given by

This can be simplified

Finally, Proposition 2 must be proved. From the assumptions we have

With we get

and the integral is given by

This was to be shown.

5.3. Proof of Proposition 3Recall Eq. ( 3 )

≥ 1 ⟺ x − 1 ≤ ε.1 + ε

x

x − 1 ≤ −a

f (x) = 1 dε = 1.∫a

−a

1

2a

−a ≤ x − 1 ≤ a

f (x) = min ( , 1) dε + min ( , 1) dε.∫x−1

−a

1 + ε

x

1

2a ∫a

x−1

1 + ε

x

1

2a

f (x)= dε + 1 ⋅ dε∫x−1

−a

1 + ε

x

1

2a ∫a

x−1

1

2a

= + − (x + ) .1

2

1

2a

1

4a

(1 − a)2

x

l (1 − τ) ≤ ⟹ l (1 − τ) ≤ (1 + ).rf

WACCinft

CFut+1

CFut

rf

WACCεt

x = l (1 − τ)rf

WACC

1 ≤ ,1 + εt

x

f (x) = [min ( , 1)] = [1] = 1.EQ

1 + εt

xEQ

T = τ min( , ).St CFut rfDt−1

Page 16: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 16/19

A6(A6)

A7(A7)

A8(A8)

From this, for the levered firm with constant amounts of debt

Obviously, we must now distinguish two cases. If (“sufficientlysmall amount of debt”), it is the known case

and therefore, as with symmetric taxation

However, if (“sufficiently large amount of debt”), then

applies. From this follows directly

Note that must be provided. Hence, for sufficiently small the ETR maybe vanishingly small, but can never become negative. For sufficiently large debt,the ETR is positive and independent of the extent of debt. As a result, in thegeneral case (where applies) we realize that

must hold.

Furthermore, ETR is a monotonically increasing function in , starting at where . Consequently, for increasing , the effective tax shield ratiomust grow from to .

This completes the proof.

References

= + τ .V l0 V u

0 ∑t=1

∞ [min( , D)]EQ CFut rf

(1 + rf )t

D ≤rf CFut

= + τDV l0 V u

0

= τ .ETRcase 1asymmetric l0

D >rf CFut

= + τ = (1 + τ)V l0 V u

0 ∑t=1

∞[ ]EQ CFu

t

(1 + rf )tV u

0

= .ETRcase 2asymmetric

τ

1 + τ

≥ 0l0 D

min( , D)CFut rf

≤ τ min ( , )ETRasymmetric l01

1 + τ

D D = 0

ETR = τl0 D

τl0τ

1+τ

Page 17: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 17/19

Blouin et al.(2010) Blouin, Jennifer L., John E. Core, and Wayne R. Guay.2010. Have the Tax Benefits of Debt Been Overestimated? Journal ofFinancial Economics 98:195–213.

Canefield(1999) Canefield, Dominica. 1999. Some Remarks on the Valuationof Firms. Journal of Valuation 4:23–25.

Dwenger and Walch(2014) Dwenger, Nadja, and Florian Walch. 2014. TaxLosses and Firm Investment: Evidence from Tax Statistics. Discussion Paper.Hohenheim: Universität Hohenheim.

Graham(1996a) Graham, John R. 1996a. Debt and the Marginal Tax Rate.Journal of Financial Economics 41:41–73.

Graham(1996b) Graham, John R. 1996b. Proxies for the Corporate MarginalTax Rat. Journal of Financial Economics 42:187–221.

Graham(2000) Graham, John R. 2000. How Big are the Tax Benefits of Debt.Journal of Finance 55:1901–1941.

Graham(2003) Graham, John R. 2003. Taxes and Corporate Finance: AReview. Review of Financial Studies 16:1075–1129.

Graham(2006) Graham, John R. 2006. A Review of Taxes and CorporateFinance. Foundations and Trends in Finance 1:573–691.

Graham and Kim(2009) Graham, John R., and Kim Hyunseob. 2009. TheEffects of the Length of the Tax­Loss Carryback Period on Tax Receipts andCorporate Marginal Tax Rates. National Tax Journal 62:413–427.

Graham and Mills(2008) Graham, John R., and Lillian F. Mills. 2008. UsingTax Return Data to Simulate Corporate Marginal Tax Rates. Journal ofAccounting and Economics 46:366–388.

Hiriart­Urruty and Lemarechal(2001) Hiriart­Urruty, Jean­Baptiste, andClaude Lemaréchal. 2001. Fundamentals of Convex Analysis. BerlinHeidelberg: Springer.

Koch(2013) Koch, Reinald (2013): “Entscheidungs­undAufkommenswirkungen der Unternehmensbesteuerung”. UnveröffentlichteHabilitationsschrift. Göttingen: Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultät derGeorg­August­Universität Göttingen

Page 18: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 18/19

Kruschwitz and Löffler(2006) Kruschwitz, Lutz, and Andreas Löffler. 2006.Discounted Cash Flow: A Theory of the Valuation of Firms. Chichester: JohnWiley & Sons.

Kruschwitz and Löffler(2015) Kruschwitz, Lutz, and Andreas Löffler. 2015.Transversality and the Stochastic Nature of Cash Flows. Modern Economy6:755–769.

Miles and Ezzell(1980) Miles, James A., and John R. Ezzell. 1980. TheWeighted Average Cost of Capital, Perfect Capital Markets, and Project Life:A Clarification. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 15:719–730.

Modigliani and Miller(1963) Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller.1963. Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction.American Economic Review 53:433–443.

Myers et al.(1998) Myers, Stewart C., John J. McConnell, A. Peterson, D.Soter, and J. Stern. 1998. Vanderbuilt University Roundtable on the CapitalStructure Puzzle. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 11:8–24.

Sarkar(2008) Sarkar, Sudipto. 2008. Can Tax Convexity Be Ignored inCorporate Financing Decisions? Journal of Banking and Finance 32:1310–1321.

Sarkar(2014) Sarkar, Sudipto. 2014. Valuation of Tax Loss Carryforwards.Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 43:803–828.

Shevlin(1990) Shevlin, Terrence J. 1990. Estimating Corporate Marginal TaxRates with Asymmetric Tax Treatment of Gains and Losses. Journal of theAmerican Taxation Association 12:51–67.

Waegenaere et al.(2003) de Waegenaere, Anja, Richard C. Sansing, and JaccoL. Wielhouwer. 2003. Valuation of a Firm with a Tax Loss Carryover. Journalof the American Taxation Association 25:65–82.

Loss carry­back is granted, for example, in the United States, France, Germany, United Kingdom,and Japan. The carry­back volume is unlimited with the exception of Germany and carry­back

periods range from 1 to 3 years. Many countries offer schemes for loss carry­forward. Germany,

again, limits the carry­forward volume. Periods, in which tax losses carried forward are valid, range

from 5 years to infinity. See Dwenger and Walch ( 2014 ) or Canefield ( 1999 ).

Waegenaere et al. ( 2003 ) discuss the valuation of carry­forward losses.

1

2

3

Page 19: V a l u i n g t h e T a x S h i e l d u n d e r A s y m m ... · 10.4.2017 e.Proofing 1

10.4.2017 e.Proofing

http://eproofing.springer.com/journals/printpage.php?token=6xcjryyI9zsX1Bw3sjVK4VOMT_FspCqK 19/19

Currently, six of the G20­countries (Brazil, Germany, France, Italy, Japan, Saudi Arabia) applysuch regulations to restrict loss carry­forward provisions by a certain proportion of profit. In the US,

loss carry­backs are similarly restricted. Losses are ultimately lost in Germany if (within five years)

more than one half of the equity is transfered to a new entity (§8c Abs. 1 Satz 1–4 KStG). In the US

section 382 of the IRC limits the use of the tax loss carryover of a corporation that is acquired in a

merger or stock purchase. The annual limitation is the product of the value of the acquired

corporation and the long­term tax­exempt interest rate, see IRC § 382(b)(1).

The existence of this risk­neutral measure is called the fundamental theorem and has been usedextensively in option pricing.

This assumption is now standard in the valuation literature, for formal details of this approach seeKruschwitz and Löffler ( 2006 , Chap. 1). Notice that our assumption ( 1 ) is slightly different from

the literature (multiplicative instead of additive noise). This is due to the fact that only with

multiplicative noise terms a meaningful valuation result can be established, see the discussion of

transversality in Kruschwitz and Löffler ( 2015 , Sects. 3.1 and 3.2).

Kruschwitz and Löffler ( 2006 , Chap. 3) and in particular Sect. 3.2 discuss the problems withpersonal income taxes and valuation.

The symbol means .

The relation of a constant or even deterministic cost of capital to the assumptions cited above isnot straightforward. See Kruschwitz and Löffler ( 2006 , Chap. 1) for details.

Notice that is a random variable. Therefore, a general definition of concavity has to be

applied. However, even with this definition the function is well known to be concave for

any . The expectation is then the sum of concave functions with a positive scalar and is also

concave. For details see Hiriart­Urruty and Lemarechal ( 2001 , Chap. B.1, Proposition 2.1.1).

We have moved the proof to the Appendix.

For a calculation of the function see the Appendix.

See Appendix for evidence. We would like to thank a reviewer for pointing us to that fact.

Again, the proof is in the Appendix. See (A6 ) in the Appendix. See Kruschwitz and Löffler ( 2006 , p. 42f.).

3

4

5

6

7X+ max(X, 0)

8

9Dt

min(x, ⋅)

x

10

11f (⋅)

12

13

14

15

16