46
Jena Research Papers in Business and Economics Exploiting Valuable Knowledge: Appro- priation Problems, Uncertainty and the Value of Licensing Agreements Andreas Bausch and Christian Grube 27/2007 Jenaer Schriften zur Wirtschaftswissenschaft Working and Discussion Paper Series School of Economics and Business Administration Friedrich-Schiller-University Jena ISSN 1864-3108 Publisher: Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultät Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena Carl-Zeiß-Str. 3, D-07743 Jena www.jbe.uni-jena.de Editor: Prof. Dr. Hans-Walter Lorenz [email protected] Prof. Dr. Armin Scholl [email protected] www.jbe.uni-jena.de

Jena Research Papers in Business and Economics file1 An earlier version of this paper has been presented at the 66th Annual Meeting of the Academy of Management 2006 in Atlanta, Georgia

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Jena Research Papers in Business and Economics

Exploiting Valuable Knowledge: Appro-priation Problems, Uncertainty

and the Value of Licensing Agreements

Andreas Bausch and Christian Grube

27/2007

Jenaer Schriften zur Wirtschaftswissenschaft

Working and Discussion Paper Series School of Economics and Business Administration

Friedrich-Schiller-University Jena

ISSN 1864-3108 Publisher:

Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultät Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena Carl-Zeiß-Str. 3, D-07743 Jena

www.jbe.uni-jena.de

Editor:

Prof. Dr. Hans-Walter [email protected]

Prof. Dr. Armin [email protected]

www.jbe.uni-jena.de

1

Exploiting Valuable Knowledge:

Appropriation Problems, Uncertainty and the Value of

Licensing Agreements

Prof. Dr. Andreas Bausch

Dipl.-Kfm. Christian Grube

Working Paper

April 2007

2

Exploiting Valuable Knowledge: Appropriation Problems, Uncertainty and the Value of

Licensing Agreements ................................................................................................................. 3

1. Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 3

2. Theoretical Background ....................................................................................................... 5

2.1. Exploiting knowledge through licensing......................................................................... 5 2.1.1. Knowledge: Content and types............................................................................ 5 2.1.2. Purpose of licensing contracts............................................................................. 7

2.2. The life cycle of a licensing contract: A two stage model .............................................. 9 2.3. Stage one: Negotiation period ....................................................................................... 10

2.3.1. Negotiation period: Licensor’s perspective....................................................... 11 2.3.2. Negotiation period: Licensee’s perspective ...................................................... 12

2.4. Stage two: Contract period............................................................................................ 13 2.4.1. Contract period: Duration and termination ....................................................... 13 2.4.2. Contract period: Compensation provisions ....................................................... 13

2.5. Hypotheses .................................................................................................................... 15 2.5.1. Hypotheses: Negotiation period ........................................................................ 15 2.5.2. Hypotheses: Contract period ............................................................................. 17

3. Empirical results ................................................................................................................. 19

3.1. Data collection and transformation ............................................................................... 19 3.2. Variables ....................................................................................................................... 21

3.2.1. Dependent variable............................................................................................ 21 3.2.2. Independent variables........................................................................................ 22

3.3. Sample description ........................................................................................................ 23 3.4. Multivariate analysis ..................................................................................................... 24

4. Discussion............................................................................................................................. 25

5. Conclusions and further research...................................................................................... 31

3

Exploiting Valuable Knowledge: Appropriation Problems, Uncertainty and the

Value of Licensing Agreements 1

1. Introduction

In the age of globalization, knowledge is one of a firm’s key resources to achieve

sustainable economic growth. But not only is a broad repository of valuable knowledge

of importance but also an effective value appropriation strategy. The need for the latter

is rooted in the intangible nature of knowledge. Arrow (1962; 1971) was the first to

recognize and investigate this intangible nature of knowledge-based resources and how

it affects the distribution of economic rents between resource owner and other players in

a market economy.

Prior to a market transaction, the seller of a knowledge asset must first convince

potential buyers from the value of his or her offer by communicating its content.

However, this content is the main, or most often even the only, value driver of explicit

knowledge. If this pre-transaction transfer can be realized at close to zero marginal cost,

it will simultaneously satisfy a potential buyer’s need and further impede any

subsequent market transaction. For decades, economists have analyzed this underlying

problem of the information paradox (Arrow, 1971; Winter, 2006).

1 An earlier version of this paper has been presented at the 66th Annual Meeting of the Academy of

Management 2006 in Atlanta, Georgia. The authors thank two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments.

4

Complex contracts are among the solutions offered to overcome this essential problem.

In case of innovations, licensing agreements are one type of performance-oriented

contracts used to exploit the value embedded in technical knowledge (Teece, 1986).

Licensing activities have motivated a large body of literature covering topics like

reasons for (Arora and Fosfuri, 2003; Mottner and Johnson, 2000; Saracho, 2002) and

results of (Arrow, 1962; Rockett, 1990) granting licenses, profit maximizing licensing

strategies (Fosfuri, 2006; Kamien and Tauman, 2002; Katz and Shapiro, 1986; Poddar

and Sinha, 2004), ways to distribute the value created between licensor and licensee

(Kamien and Tauman, 1986), timing of licensing (before or after developing a

technology) (Gallini, 1984; Gallini and Winter, 1985; Shapiro, 1985) and the types of

innovations that are transferred (Arora, 1995; Katz and Shapiro, 1985).

One stream of research analyzes in detail the information given by licensing

agreements. Major contributions have been made by Taylor et al. (1973), Caves et al.

(1983), Rostoker (1983), Contractor (1981; 1985) Macho-Stadler et al. (1996), Aulakh

et al. (1998), Bessy et al. (1998). Anand et al. (2000) and Nagaoka et al. (2006). So far,

most of the research carried out in this field has been focused on describing the different

features of licensing agreements. This paper particularly contributes to research by

investigating the relationship between the financial value of a licensing agreement and

its content. Thereby, we answer the following research questions: (1) Does an effective

market mechanism for technical knowledge exist? and (2) Which contractual terms

drive the value of a licensing agreement?

5

2. Theoretical Background

2.1. Exploiting knowledge through licensing

2.1.1. Knowledge: Content and types

Licensing agreements are one specific class of contracts used to exploit technological

knowledge in collaboration with an external partner. Understanding the essential role

that licensing agreements play in the process of generating value out of knowledge

assets requires in a first step to analyze content and features of these assets. As for the

first, the existing body of literature shows a variety of different approaches to describe

the content of knowledge. However, economic theory still lacks a precise and

commonly accepted definition. Some economic theorists analyze knowledge following

the ideas of epistemology, the branch of philosophy investigating concept, origin and

reliability of knowledge (Nonaka and Takeuchi, 1995; Spender, 1996).2 Other economic

thinkers argue that knowledge is just ‘the state of knowing’ (Machlup, 1980:56) or ‘that

which is known’ (Grant, 1996:110). Today, it is widely recognized that ‘knowledge is

grounded on information’ (Caldwell, 1975:570) which is interpreted by the knowing

entity (Huber, 1991) and, following Plato’s justified belief approach, assumed (Nonaka,

1994) or proofed (Liebeskind, 1996) to be true.

One approach to reduce the diversity of knowledge definitions is an analysis along the

following two dimensions: (1) time and (2) type. With regard to the general economic

transformation process we can either interpret knowledge as an input factor or as output

of corporate processes and, thus, as a corporate asset (Barney, 1991; Itami and Roehl,

2 This philosophical discussion can be traced back to Aristotle and Plato and has been resumed throughout

the centuries by various thinkers like e.g. René Descartes, John Locke, Immanuel Kant, Jon Dewey and Gilbert Ryle.

6

1987; Quinn, 1992; Teece, 1998) that exists at a specific point in time. Or, applying a

more dynamic view, as a facilitator in the production process emphasizing the

supportive role of knowledge and its potential to increase efficiency in the process of

combining different inputs (Arrow and Hahn, 1971; Penrose, 1959; Spender, 1996).

The elements of the second dimension, type, are explicit and implicit knowledge. This

split can be traced back to Polanyi (1966) who coined the term of tacit knowing. He

bases his ideas on the observation of the limited ability of human beings to fully express

verbally all what they do know. Citing several experiments conducted by Lazarus and

McCleary (1949; 1951), Polanyi argues that some parts of human knowledge are

connected by a functional relationship of which the knowing individual is not fully

aware. Or, in more popular words, the quintessence of tacit knowing consists of the

observation that individuals do know more than they can tell (Polanyi, 1966).

Scholars have taken up this idea by defining tacit knowledge as a superordinate concept

for all those parts of knowledge that cannot be fully expressed, defined or codified.3

This economic interpretation of the tacit nature of knowledge has been further shaped in

contrast to explicit knowledge.4 The explicitness of knowledge enables the knowing

individual to codify5, formalize and systematize knowledge. In turn, this process of

standardization facilitates both, transferability and protection of knowledge using

3 However, although the wording seems comparably, differences do exist regarding the meaning of both

concepts. While Polanyi assumes that tacit knowing only exists if the individual is unaware of its very existence and that concentrating and focusing on tacit knowing lead to its destruction, economic theorists in general interpret tacit knowledge as being inexpressible and hence difficult to transfer voluntarily or involuntarily (Nelson et al., 1982). They allow one to be aware of one’s tacit knowledge but at the same time to be unable to articulate it.

4 Synonyms for this dichotomy are codified and uncodified (Choi and Lee, 1997; Teece, 1998), objective and subjective, prepositional and personal, declarative and procedural (Grant, 1996; Kakabadse, et al., 2001; Nahapiet and Ghoshal, 1998; Winter, 1987), internal and external (Zack, 1999) or alienable and non-alienable (Brynjolfsson, 1994; Foss, 2002) knowledge.

5 In this context, codification refers to the possibility to compress knowledge into a specific, standardized expression which can be understood by everyone who is acquainted with this way of expression (Boisot and Child, 1988)

7

intellectual property rights (IPRs) (Mudambi and Navarra, 2004; Nonaka and Takeuchi,

1995; Teece, 1998).

Explicit knowledge is a public good (Arrow, 1962; Dyer and Nobeoka, 2000; Grant,

2002; Kogut and Zander, 1993; Machlup, 1980; Martin and Salomon, 2003). Once

communicated, the resource owner can neither fully control access to nor consumption

of this resource. In addition, non rivalry in consumption does exist (Arrow, 1962; Ba, et

al., 2001; Grant, 1996). Consequently, the value potential embedded in this resource

cannot be fully appropriated by the resource owner in the absence of any additional

appropriation strategies (Arrow, 1962).

Contrary to the public character of explicit knowledge, tacit knowledge is of completely

private nature. This property affects the transferability diametrically to the case of

explicit knowledge. It is not easily visible, expressible and therefore only transferable to

a limited extent (Nonaka, 1991; 1994; Nonaka and Takeuchi, 1995). A shift from one

individual to another is slowly, costly and uncertain (Arora, 1995; Grant, 1996; Kogut

and Zander, 1992; Nelson and Winter, 1982; Teece, 1977). The only ways to transfer

tacit knowledge are teaching (Penrose, 1959; Winter, 1987) or imitating the actions

which are performed using tacit knowledge (Polanyi, 1958, 1966; Teece, 1986).

2.1.2. Purpose of licensing contracts

According to Teece (1986) and his classical work on profiting from innovations,

licensing agreements are particular advantageous under a strong appropriability regime

and in the presence of complementary assets. However, if the subject of contract is an

innovation or other technical knowledge then these contracts hold a danger of

opportunistic behavior on both sides. Bessy and Brousseau (1998) further emphasize

8

that a knowledge transfer can induce the creation of new knowledge that in turn can

substitute or devalue the knowledge originally transferred. Due to these limitations,

complex contractual agreements are needed in order to exploit the economic potential of

knowledge in the marketplace.

One major advantage of licensing agreements is that they can deal with any type of

knowledge. They can be used to transfer not only explicit knowledge in the form of

IPRs or documents like manuals, blueprints or technical handbooks but also tacit

components through offering technical assistance and educational services (Anand and

Khanna, 2000; Arora, 1995).

The primary objective of a licensing agreement is to define the specific rights and duties

of both contracting parties. Based on this agreement, the licensor transfers his or her

property rights of the subject of the contract to the licensee for a specific period of time

in exchange for some sort of compensation (Manfroy, 2002; Sullivan, 1996). In contrast

to a contract of sale, the licensor or knowledge owner retains title to the property and

only temporarily allows the licensee to exercise a well defined bundle of owner specific

rights (Contractor, 1985).

By granting licenses for explicit knowledge, licensors can overcome appropriabilty

problems. First of all, this reduces its public nature. Furthermore, if they do not grant an

exclusive license, licensors can take advantage of the feature of non rivalry in

consumption. This allows multiple transactions of the same knowledge content with

different licensees. In the case of tacit knowledge, licensing agreements are one way to

control knowledge flows between licensor and licensee.

For licensees one major advantage of this flexible nature of licensing contracts is that

they can avoid the risk of being sued for infringing property rights related to explicit

9

knowledge and with the same contract can profit from implicit or tacit components of

knowledge.

Although neither content nor structure of licensing agreements are legally defined,

several recurring features can be found in each contract (Bryer, 1999; Contractor, 1985;

Merwin and Warner, 1996) allowing a comparison and statistical analyses of its content.

All licensing agreements contain information about the identities of the participating

firms, subject of the contract, purpose of the contract, number and characteristics of

rights granted, compensation provisions and expected lifetime.

2.2. The life cycle of a licensing contract: A two stage model

We can split the entire lifetime of an agreement into two consecutive stages. The first

stage, the negotiation period, comprises a series of meetings during which licensor and

licensee discuss the specific features of the licensing agreement. Like any other market

transaction, this period is characterized by a series of negotiations and compromises. If

both parties eventually agree, they will draft a licensing agreement to come in force at

the effective date (end of stage one, start date for stage two).

During the second stage (contract period), the licensor may use the subject of contract

as defined in the agreement. In a world with deterministic outcomes, licensor and

licensee ex ante know what future holds and what costs and benefits are associated with

this agreement. However, in reality both contracting parties face a high degree of

uncertainty regarding the economic and legal consequences of their decisions.

Especially in an economic surrounding like the electronics industry where we observe a

rapid technology development of cumulative technologies that are protected by

extensive, overlapping patent portfolios (Grindley and Teece, 1997; Reitzig, 2004) and

10

hardly predictable customer behavior, drafting and entering appropriate licensing

agreements is a key factor for sustainable economic success.

Therefore, we assume that both parties try to reduce this multifaceted uncertainty by

choosing appropriate contractual terms. During the negotiation period it is most

important for them (1) to achieve a common understanding about the subject of

contract, (2) to clearly define which rights are transferred and (3) to decide about the

features of these rights. With regard to the unknown future, the parties must implement

contractual clauses that define not only (1) the duration and (2) termination of the

contract but also (3) how the licensee shall compensate the licensor for the transfer of

rights.

2.3. Stage one: Negotiation period

Before and during the negotiation period, both parties form expectations about the

strategic and economic value that results from a possible licensing contract. A

successful outcome of any negotiation requires that their expectations coincide, at least

partially. Since each party also takes into consideration the value expectations of the

opposite party and since all expectations are based on a set of assumptions, licensee and

licensor will estimate not only single values but entire value ranges for the respective

technology.

Following the model of Contractor (1985), we identify borders of each value range

based on expected costs and benefits.

--------------------------------

Insert Figure 1 about here

--------------------------------

11

2.3.1. Negotiation period: Licensor’s perspective

The transfer of technological knowledge is costly (Teece, 1977). These transfer costs

define the minimum acceptable value from the licensor’s perspective. They comprise

e.g. costs for delivering explicit knowledge like documents, manuals or patents and

costs for transferring implicit knowledge induced by teaching licensee’s engineers and

offering support and ongoing assistance over the entire duration of the agreement. If the

purpose of the contract is to penetrate a foreign market or if an exclusive license is

granted, than opportunity costs have to be added in order to estimate a threshold value

since the choice of licensing as form of market entry theoretically rules the possibilities

for export or foreign direct investment out (Contractor, 1981). In the case of granting an

exclusive license, opportunity costs arise since the licensor is bound by the contract not

to grant this specific license to other potential licensees.

The maximum value from the licensor’s perspective equals either the sum of transfer

costs, opportunity costs and the present value of all cash flows the licensor expects the

licensee to obtain over the lifespan of the agreement (A1) or the sum of transfer costs,

opportunity costs and the present value of all costs, the licensor expects the licensee to

incur in order to obtain the respective technology elsewhere (A2). As for the latter, we

agree with Farok Contractors argumentation but for the former we suggest that for both,

licensee and licensor, not only the present value of future cash flows is of importance

but also the degree, to which both, licensor and licensee, expect an appropriation of

these cash flows.

12

2.3.2. Negotiation period: Licensee’s perspective

From a licensee’s perspective, the most favorable contract would grant a license free of

charge. However, since both parties have entered a negotiation process, the licensee will

form expectations about licensor’s transfer costs and take these into consideration in

assessing a minimum value for the respective technology. The maximum costs the

licensee will be willing to accept depend on the options available to get access to this

technology. If we assume that the licensee wishes to bridge a technological gap through

licensing and to exploit the economic potential of the respective technology, the

maximum value equals the sum of the discounted incremental profits or cost savings

that can be yielded by using this technology (B4). This has been the predominant

motivation for the sample of licensing contracts analyzed in this paper. However, value

expectations can be driven by other factors as well. Instead of asking for a license, the

licensee could also set up an own R&D project to either develop a similar technology or

to invent around the licensor’s patents (B3). Alternatively, the licensee could try to find

a similar technology offered by a different licensor in order to substitute the negotiated

technology (B2). If the licensee requires a permission to use a specific technology only

to avoid an infringement process, a fourth option includes calculating a net present

value of the costs for such a litigation process (B1). These costs do not consist of

expenses for legal advice and costs of the proceedings only. Since the patent owner can

obtain a preliminary injunction against any further value exploitation activities

conducted by the infringing party, costs of lost sales and earnings must also be taken

into account (Grudziecki and Michel, 2002).

If the expected value ranges of licensor and licensee overlap, a successful signing of the

contract seems to be likely. The contractual features then mirror the expectations of

13

both, licensor and licensee as well as their individual bargaining power. We recognize

that the latter can hardly be measured reliably. But since these agreements are

negotiated by experts led more by clear interests and less by emotions, we assume that

the contracts we investigate are ‘wise agreements’ (Fisher and Ury, 1982) that meet the

interests of both parties, allow for a fair solution of conflicting interests and are durable.

2.4. Stage two: Contract period

2.4.1. Contract period: Duration and termination

The compensation provisions answer the question how the licensee shall compensate

the licensor during the contract period. But before the parties can decide about this

specific feature, they must first agree upon a clear definition of the lifetime of the

agreement. If the contract deals with patents, it usually terminates at the expiry date of

the last patent. For the electronics industry, Taylor and Silberston (1973) report that, as

the subject of contract in most cases also comprises unprotected know how, licensor and

licensee define a shorter period and implement prolongation clauses. If both contracting

parties fail to give notice by a certain predefined date that they do not wish to extend the

duration of the term then these clauses automatically extent the validity of the

agreement. In contrast to this prolongation, both parties can also define situations in

which one party can void the contract. These termination rules matter in case that one

party infringes a substantial condition of the agreement.

2.4.2. Contract period: Compensation provisions

Empirical results show a considerable variety of compensation provisions (Aulakh, et

al., 1998; Bessy and Brousseau, 1998; Merwin and Warner, 1996). Apart from lump

14

sum payments, the most common means to determine license fees are recurring amount

payments and royalty rates. Royalty rates can either be defined as an absolute amount to

be paid on a per unit base or as a percentage of sales volume or more precisely of the

net selling price6. In addition, a royalty rate either remains stable (flat royalty) or

changes with regard to the development of the royalty base. In the latter case, licensor

and licensee agree upon a schedule defining the adjustments of the royalty rate to be

made if the base, e.g. the sales volume or the number of units sold, exceeds predefined

thresholds. Finally, recurring amount payments are either due after the completion of

different steps in an overall process (e.g. product development) or at predefined future

dates. In our sample we find three main compensation mechanisms: (1) a fix component

comprising lump sum and (2) recurring amount payments and (3) a variable component,

consisting of a schedule of declining royalty rates.

If both parties agree upon a running royalty rate then the licensor’s revenue (royalty

income) is directly linked to the exploitation of the respective technology by the

licensee (Cho, 1988). From the perspective of the licensor, the financial value of a

license therefore depends not only on the economic potential, or more precisely on the

stream of profits the licensee generates by exploiting these rights, but also on the degree

to which he or she can appropriate a satisfying part of this stream via the compensation

formula. Therefore, the transaction value of a license agreement V(L0) from the

licensor’s perspective at time t = 0 is given by:

0

T

1t

T

1t0t

tt

ttb0 φ*LS

)c1(RA

)c1(rr*)V(r

)V(L ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+

++

+= ∑ ∑

= =

(1)

6 This price is usually calculated as the price of contract products charged to customers after allowing

deductions for value-added tax, costs for packing, transport and insurance, applicable import-export and excise duties, returns and trade discounts. Besides these two bases, royalty rates might also be defined as percentage of the gross margin or the profit before or after taxes (Perlitz, 1980).

15

with V(rb)t as value of the royalty base in t, rrt as royalty rate in t, RAt as recurring

amount payments in t, LS0 as lump sum payment in period 0, c as cost of capital and T

as duration of the agreement. φ0 denotes an appropriability factor which determines the

extent to which the licensor can appropriate the value calculated by the compensation

formula.

In addition to this financial value, both parties might agree upon a reciprocal exchange

of knowledge or patents. From the perspective of each party, such a cross-license

(Taylor and Silberston, 1973:116) creates the advantage to avoid development costs for

a complementary technology and allows an earlier introduction of a product based on

each partners’ technology. But at the same time this also provokes the creation of

substitutes for the products of each partner (Fershtman and Kamien, 1992). Moreover,

cross-licensing might foster collusive behavior of both parties since it either increases

(in the case of imperfect substitutes) the probability of a market entry (Eswaran, 1993)

and/or enables each party to directly influence the pricing or distribution strategy of the

respective partner (Shapiro, 1985).

2.5. Hypotheses

2.5.1. Hypotheses: Negotiation period

The overall aim of a licensing agreement is to determine the rights and duties of both

parties. In general, we can identify four classes of property rights (Alchian and

Demsetz, 1973; Coase, 1960; Demsetz, 1967) that can be licensed. A licensee can

obtain the right (1) to use, (2) consume and (3) obtain income from and (4) to alienate

attributes of the subject of contract. Attributes comprise all different operation modes

and application areas of this resource (Foss and Foss, 2005). Since a contract is one of

16

the primary sources of information in case of any legal proceedings and provides the

basis for a successful business relationship, it must not only cover all important aspects

of subsequent transactions but must also be written in a clear and precise style (Ramsay,

2002).

Of course, multiple formulations can be used to express the rights granted. The right to

use is reflected in a licensing agreement by giving the permission to utilize the subject

of contract as defined in the agreement. In contrast to this, granting rights to produce or

manufacture specific goods based on the traded technology corresponds to the right of

the licensee to exploit this technology within the production process in every way that

might seem suitable, thus to consume this technology in order to produce a specific

output. The granting of rights to market or sell products and services enables the

licensee to obtain income from the attributes of this technology, whereas the right to

sublicense qualifies to generate profits from selling and, thus, alienating the respective

technology.

The impact of these different classes of rights derives from the fact that they do not only

determine the size of the market in which the licensee can operate but also the means by

which he or she can penetrate this market. Furthermore, by a precise and extensive

specification of the license, licensee and licensor can reduce uncertainty regarding the

rights granted. Based on these reflections we hypothesize:

Hypothesis 1: The more rights are granted, the higher the transaction value will be.

A clear and precise formulation of the rights granted requires in first step to create a

common understanding of concepts that describe specific rights and duties. Therefore,

17

every contract contains one section in which definitions of key contractual terms, like

‘contracting products’ or ‘transferred rights’, are given.

On the one hand, introducing definitions for key contractual terms allows a clearly

arranged description of the license. On the other hand, an extensive definition of these

terms again reduces uncertainty during the negotiation period and facilitates an efficient

problem solving process in case of any future problems between the contracting parties

Thus, we assume:

Hypothesis 2: The degree of accuracy applied to define contractual terms

increases the transaction value.

Having exclusive access to important resources is vital for achieving and securing

competitive advantages (Barney, 1991). The highest offer a licensor can make is the

grant of an exclusive license to a third party. Since this decision narrows the window of

opportunity for the licensor and chancels the possibility of profiting from the feature of

non rivalry in consumption opportunity costs arise. In presence of an efficient market

mechanism, these additional costs increase the licensor’s threshold (Merwin and

Warner, 1996). Therefore we hypothesize:

Hypothesis 3: The decision for an exclusive license increases the transaction value.

2.5.2. Hypotheses: Contract period

Based on an analysis of 46 contracts, Bessy and Brousseau (1998) identify five different

kinds of licensing agreements. One distinguishing feature between these five classes is

the existence of contractual terms referring to cross-licenses. In one class, Bessy and

18

Brousseau (1998) refer to as ‘development technology licenses’, no other compensation

mechanisms are implemented besides a pure cross-license. In the case of cross-licensing

agreements licensor and licensee may not only consider technology primarily as a

source of future revenue but as a currency or a bargaining chip to be used during the

negotiation process in order to achieve their individual objectives (McEvily, et al.,

2004; Nickerson, 1996). In view of these considerations, we interpret the existence of

contractual terms referring to cross-licenses as an equal mean to compensate the

licensor and, therefore, assume:

Hypothesis 4: Cross-licensing clauses negatively affects transaction value.

Based on their analysis of the semiconductor and electronics industry, Grindley and

Teece (1997) distinguish two types of (cross-) licensing contracts: They identify a

capture model, that entitles the licensee to use all the patents within a technology field

not only during the license period but until they expire. In contrast to this, if both parties

agree on a fixed period licensing model, the contract is only valid over a predefined life

span. In order to prolong this kind of agreement both parties must enter renegotiations.

Grindely and Teece (1997) state that the latter facilitates more flexibility since licensor

and licensee can periodically adjust the agreement to reflect environmental and

technological changes.

If both parties agree on a renewal clause, then the existing contract will be automatically

renewed after a specific time span and changes of contractual features require a

renegotiation of the entire contract. Thus, we argue that renewal clauses reduce

flexibility and hypothesize:

Hypothesis 5: Renewal clauses negatively affect transaction value.

19

Another source for uncertainty is the probability that the existing contract is incomplete

since both parties either do not take all possible future circumstances into account or

that it is to costly to design a contract that reflects all the relevant scenarios in sufficient

detail (Brynjolfsson, 1994). If contracts are of incomplete nature, problems may arise

such as the unwillingness to fulfill specific contractual duties (Rabin, 1993). In the

absence of precise stipulations, these problems can only be solved by costly trials.

Therefore, both parties agree upon termination clauses that allow them to react by

canceling the respective contract if the environment or their individual situation is

changing in an unforeseen way. Therefore, we assume:

Hypothesis 6: The degree of accuracy applied to define termination rules increases

the transaction value.

3. Empirical results

3.1. Data collection and transformation

To test our hypotheses, we have collected 191 single licensing agreements which we

obtained from various companies active in the electronics industry by personal contact.

To ensure a high degree of comparability within the sample, we defined five selection

criteria to be met by each contract. First, the contract must have been negotiated by a

member of a company wide licensing department. The existence of a licensing

department, either being independent or being part of a company wide legal department

is required in order to assure that value exploitation via licensing out activities is

intended to happen on a regular base. Second, both parties of the contract must have

been legally unrelated on the signing date. This criterion is essential for analyzing

20

market transactions at arm’s length only and to avoid including intra-firm licensing

agreements that define internal transfer prices and aim at reducing tax payments on a

company level (Kopits, 1976). Third, subject of the contract must either be

technological knowledge in explicit form (like e.g. a single patent or patent portfolio) or

in implicit, thus tacit form (like e.g. training or services). Fourth, we only included

contracts that were used to transfer technological knowledge in exchange for (financial)

payments in combination with granting cross-licenses or financial payments only. We

excluded every single pure cross-licensing agreement. Fifth, the licensor’s predominant

aim must be to commercialize the value potential embedded in the respective

technology. We did not include cases in which licensing agreements served other

purposes, e.g. supporting an internationalization strategy.

We carefully read all contracts and coded them following the model of Srnka and

Koeszegi (2007) for transforming qualitative information into quantitative data. This

model consists of five separate stages. The first two stages comprise (1) collection and

(2) transcription of qualitative data. If the data are already available in written from (as

it is the case for licensing agreements) these two stages can be omitted. However, most

important in these initial stages of the transformation process is to create and ensure a

sufficient degree of comparability within the sample. One major concern here is to deal

with language differences. Due to semantic differences and cultural phenomena,

comparing documents written in different languages may lead to misinterpretations

which in turn prevent the construction of a comparable dataset. In view of this and since

the majority of contracts is written in English, we exclude any licensing agreement

composed in another language. This reexamination process led to a sample size of 141

contracts.

21

Stage three (unitization) and four (categorization) focus on defining appropriate units of

analysis and on structuring and condensing data. For our sample we take advantage of

the fact that several recurring features and a comparable structure can be found in each

contract (e.g. the identities of the participating firms, subject of the contract, purpose of

the contract, number and characteristics of rights granted, compensation provisions and

time frame). Since we had access to the full text version of the documents we decided

for stage five (coding) to code any common aspect of the contracts. Of course, this

implies devoting a considerable amount of time to coding and consistency checks. On

the one hand, such a comprehensive analysis allows an in depth analysis of contractual

features but, given a predefined time span for data collection, at the same time also

limits the number of contracts that can be coded.

3.2. Variables

3.2.1. Dependent variable

In order to calculate the dependent variable ‘transaction value’, we compute in a first

step the value of the fix component by summing up the amount for lump sum payments

and the net present value of recurring payments. In a second step we then add the net

present value of the variable payments based on the royalty schedule defined in the

contract. In a third step we calculate the total value of the licensing agreement as sum of

both the fix and variable component. Since compensation formulas are defined in two

currencies (Euro and US-Dollar) we convert the total Euro values into a corresponding

amount of US-Dollar by multiplying the calculated transaction value by the interbank

exchange rate effective on the signing date. We assume that both contractual parties

22

either build future expectations about exchange risk on a naïve no change forecast or

apply hedging strategies to avoid currency risks.

As discussed above, compensation formulas comprise four main elements: (1) lump

sum payments, (2) recurring amount payments, (3) royalty rate payments and (4) cross-

licenses. We find all these elements and combinations of them in our sample: The great

majority of cases (84.5%) uses lump sum payments either as sole compensation

mechanism (31.0%) or in combination with royalty rates (26.1%), recurring amount

payments (4.2%) or cross-licensing agreements (23.2%).

For the remaining contracts (15.5%) licensee and licensor agree upon more than two

compensation mechanisms like lump sum, recurring amount and royalty rate (1.4%),

lump sum, royalty rate and cross-license (10.6%), lump sum, recurring amount and

cross-license (2.8%), and a combination of all four payment schemes (0.7%).

3.2.2. Independent variables

For testing our hypotheses, we define six variables. The definition of the license is

measured as number of words used for the description of the license. We assume a

positive relationship between the number of words used to describe the license and the

rights actually transferred. Of course, this implies that the number of words is not

increased by negative formulations like geographic (or technological) restrictions. We

find such restrictive clauses in a quarter of contracts (25.4%). In order to create a

comparable sample, we carefully read through all contracts and create a ‘net position’ of

this variable by subtracting the number of words used to express restrictions from the

total number of words used for describing the license.

23

We apply the same method of counting and do similar calculations for two other

variables. The degree of accuracy in defining key contractual terms equals the number

of words used for describing definitions of key contractual terms. We arrive at the

degree of accuracy for the definition of termination rules by adding up number of words

used for defining situations in which one party can void the agreement. We measure

contractual terms referring to cross-licenses, renewal options and exclusive rights as

dummy variables.

3.3. Sample description

Table 1 summarizes the main characteristics of our sample The contracts we

investigated are used to transfer Intellectual property rights (Patent applications, single

patents, patent portfolios and copyrights) and property rights for inventions, software,

software documentation, know how and hardware.

--------------------------------

Insert Table 1 about here

--------------------------------

If the subject of contract comprises more than just one item (e.g. patent portfolio and

know how) we count the number of entries for each variable separately. As can be

easily seen, intellectual property rights play an important role (84.2% of all entries are

related to at least one IPR category). In fact, more then half of the number of entries

(52.0%) are connected to a transfer of a portfolio of patents. Furthermore, an analysis of

the type of rights granted reveals that, in the majority of cases, licensors refuse to grant

the right to sublicense the subject of contract. We find contractual clauses for exclusive

rights in nearly one quarter of all contracts (22.5%). The earliest date on which licensor

24

and licensee acceded to a licensing agreement was in 1970. However, the majority of

contracts was signed between 1991 and 2000 (47.2%) and 2001 and 2005 (45.8%). This

reflects the increasing willingness of companies to extract value from their intellectual

assets that we can observe since the late 1980s (Manfroy, 2002).

A final look at geographical restrictions reveals that approximately three fourth (74.6%)

of all contracts contain no explicit geographic restriction and that the rights are granted

worldwide. Caves et al. (1983) find geographic restrictions in about one third (34%) of

the contracts they investigated and Taylor and Silberston (1973) report that of 29

companies that replied to their question about restrictive provisions, 25 state that they

explicitly or implicitly limit the markets in which a product can be sold. Interviews with

different managers, responsible for the contracts in our sample revealed the fact that a

precise formulation of geographical restrictions is often not required. On the one hand,

patent licenses already define the geographical extend in which the licensee can operate

(please recall the predominance of IPR as subject of contract). On the other hand, the

absence of an explicit formulation of such restrictions can be motivated by the aim to

avoid costly renegotiations that occur in case of extending the geographical scope of

patent protection after the signing of the contract.

3.4. Multivariate analysis

Table 2 shows the results of ordinary lest square regressions for four models with

standardized coefficients (beta) and t-values in parentheses. We used SPSS© for testing

hypotheses and examined the main underlying assumptions of all the statistical tests of

hypotheses but found no major violations. In particular, to check for multicollinearity

25

we computed variance inflation factors (for all variables below 2.7) and condition

indices (for all variables below 5.0).

We begin with a simple model that tests the impact of the breadth of rights granted, the

degree of accuracy applied for defining key contractual terms and the exclusivity of

rights. For each or the following four models we add one additional variable. The final

model (IV) then comprises all variables.

--------------------------------

Insert Table 2 about here

--------------------------------

A first look at the result of the full specified model IV (R2adj. 0.28, p < 0.01) shows that

we find strong support for hypothesis 1. The breadth of rights granted has a positive and

significant (p < 0.01) effect on the value of a licensing agreement. We can also observe

a positive and significant (p < 0.05) relationship between the degree of accuracy applied

for defining key contractual terms and the dependent variable. Furthermore, statistical

analyses reveal a negative and significant relationship between the value of a licensing

agreement and the degree of accuracy applied for defining termination rules (p < 0.01)

and the existence of prolongation clauses (p < 0.05).

4. Discussion

Following our theoretical model, we first discuss the results for the variables of the

negotiation period and then proceed with an analysis of our findings for the contract

period.

The confirmation of the first two hypotheses strongly supports the idea of a highly

effective market mechanism. In general, an effective market transaction requires that the

26

traded goods exhibit a sufficient degree of homogeneity that allows a deduction of

values and prices through comparative analyses. In fact, this criterion of homogeneity

comprises two important aspects. First, we may expect a positive correlation between

the quantity or significance of qualitative features of a good and its price. Second,

homogeneity implies that market participants share a common understanding about the

good’s nature and its features. In an active and open market where homogenous goods

are frequently traded between unrelated market participants and in the absence of

market power of one or a few of these participants, market prices therefore serve as

good indicators for the value of traded goods. In fact, this basic function of the price

system first of all enables any transaction (Hayek, 1945).

For intangible assets in general and knowledge assets in particular the hypothesis of an

existence of an active market is often rejected. However, we can observe first attempts

to establish active markets for specific intangible assets like e.g. auctions for patents and

patent portfolios. In this case, market participants try to take advantage of the fact that

an invention must meet several fundamental and procedural requirements defined by

national patent laws in order to qualify for patent protection. The strong harmonization

of different national patent laws during the last decades (Jaffe, 2000) facilitates a certain

degree of comparability of different patent rights and thus ensures a minimum level of

homogeneity.

Despite this remarkable progress, we cannot yet identify an active market for all kinds

of intangible goods. But this does not necessarily imply that these assets can not be

traded at all. Rather does the singularity of a knowledge asset rooted in its intangible

nature and related appropriation problems call for highly skilled knowledge workers

27

(Drucker, 1991) using meta-knowledge7 for evaluating the subject of contract. These

experts do not only enable any transfer of knowledge through licensing agreements but

can also guarantee a considerable level of quality regarding the technology valuation

process.

In view of our results for hypothesis one, we may conclude that they are successful in

establishing a positive relationship between the breadth of rights the licensor grants and

the financial value of a contract during the negotiation period. Thus, in the absence of

an open and active market, valuation by experts is an appropriate strategy to assess the

value for a knowledge asset.

We receive further support for this idea from the significant result for hypothesis 2. A

reduction of uncertainty by clarifying key contractual terms seems not only possible but

also valuable. In view of the legal rights and means of a patent holder and based on the

wish to reduce the probability of incomplete contracts and costly trials, an extensive

definition of these terms reduces uncertainty during the negotiation period. In the light

of the results for hypothesis 1 and 2 we may therefore further conclude that by reducing

uncertainty an increase in the quality of an agreement is possible but not at zero costs.

But if agreements are costly not only uncertainty will be reduced but also licensee’s

propensity to act opportunistically will diminish, since he or she then faces a similar

situation the licensor does before signing an agreement. Therefore, these findings can

also contribute to the debate about the best ways to protect knowledge. Means to protect

knowledge do not consist of IPRs only but also comprise secrecy (Arora, 1997;

Arundel, 2001; Cohen, et al., 2000) or selecting an appropriate organizational structure

(Spender, 1996) that (1) decreases incentives for opportunistic behavior, (2) increases

7 Meta knowledge can be defined as knowledge used in order to asses value and reliability of knowledge

as resource (Kakabadse, et al., 2001; Spender, 1996).

28

the scope of control over employees and (3) reduces their mobility (Liebeskind, 1996).

If we do not concentrate on the protection of knowledge only but more generally on the

successful exploitation of knowledge based advantages then we also have to consider

first mover advantages (Nelson, 1990) resulting from implementing a lead time strategy

and from riding down the experience curve (Winter, 1987).

The overall aim of all these protective means is to bypass the threats resulting from the

information paradox by either limiting the number of knowledge recipients (e.g.

secrecy) or by reducing the time period over which knowledge is valuable to others (e.g.

lead time). The signing of costly licensing agreements can be one mean to reduce the

number of knowledge recipients since licensors do not transfer knowledge only but

simultaneously create the need or wish on the licensee’s side to keep this knowledge

private.

If we look at the results for selected contractual features, like the exclusivity of rights

granted (hypothesis three) and the decision to grant cross licenses (hypothesis four), we

find for the first a small and negative, though insignificant relationship. Thus, based on

our sample, we cannot confirm hypothesis three. However, this negative relationship is

in line with previous empirical results. Kim and Vorontas (2004) show that the

complexity of a given technology negatively affects the tendency to grant exclusive

licenses. In industries like the electronics industry in which complex technologies are

used, IPRs are weaker and harder to enforce then in industries with discrete

technologies. In fact, patent owners in this industry report a lower reliance on protecting

technology through IPRs (Cohen, et al., 2000; Mansfield, 1986). But if IPRs are weak

then offering and granting exclusive rights might be less favorable than in other

industries with less complex technologies.

29

This weakness of IPRs in the electronics industry can also explain cross-licensing

activities. Based on the results for hypothesis four, we cannot confirm the idea of a

cross-license as substitute for monetary payments. Anand and Khanna (2000) argue that

due to this weakness companies working in this industry exhibit in general a higher

tendency to grant cross-licenses. Since weak IPRs induce substantial imitation and

inventing around activities by competitors, cross-licensing agreements might be an

efficient contracting mechanism in order to avoid costs for reengineering (Anand and

Khanna, 2000) and expensive infringement trials. Although empirical results indicate

that costs for imitating existing and protected technology are comparatively low in

electronics,8 the probability of litigation including an unfavorable court decision can

motivate cross-licensing (Ordover, 1991).

Grindley and Tecce (1997) report that in cumulative industries like electronics,

innovations are strongly interconnected. They further argue that this dependency creates

mutually blocking patent portfolios leading to a ‘Mexican standoff’ (Grindley and

Teece, 1997p. 11). In such a situation one major objective is to receive freedom to

operate in a certain technology field. Grindley and Nickerson (1996) state that cross-

licensing terms are used in order to solve this mutual blockade. Therefore, granting

cross-licenses can rather be interpreted as a precondition to be met before entering

negotiations then as a significant value driver. Clearly, granting-cross licenses might

also be a first step in order to establish a close cooperation form between licensee and

licensor. Again, in this case, the prior goal of a licensing agreement would not be to

generate profits by exploiting the economic potential of a respective technology but to

establish a faithful cooperation between both parties. Thus, we may view the of granting

8 According to Mansfield, Schwartz & Wagner (1981: 913) and Levin, Klevorick, Nelson & Winter

(1987: 811), patents generally raise imitation costs by 7 to 15 percentage points.

30

cross-licenses rather as a strategic device to deal with the specific features of the

underlying technological complexity and to improve the relationship between both

contracting parties then as a compensation mechanism.

For the negotiation period, we might summarize that two indicators describing the

content and range of the rights transferred have a positive and significant impact on

transaction values.

Turning to the results for the variables of the contract period, the negative and

significant relationship between the existence of prolongation clauses and the value of

an agreement seems to support our idea that licensor and licensee wish to maintain a

high degree of flexibility. Although we can imagine situations in which the one party

(e.g. licensor) would profit from an extension of the contract at the expense of the

second party, this result implies that both parties create negative expectations regarding

the future profitability of their present decisions. Two reasons can explain these

pessimistic expectations. First, given the predominance of IPRs as subject of transfer in

our sample, one important aspect can be that the quality, thus the value, of a patent is

not proven until it has been found valid through an infringement trial (Sherry and Teece,

2004). Second, in a world of rapid technological progress, it is in general difficult to

create reliable and consistent expectations about how a present decision affects the

economic situation of the contracting party in the future.

Based on the statistical analyses of our sample we cannot confirm hypothesis six. In

fact, transaction values decrease with an increase in the degree of accuracy for defining

termination rules. This implies that both contracting parties cannot fully rule out

uncertainties during the contracting period. Additional support for this idea comes from

31

Bessy and Brousseau (1998) who argue that uncertainty is reflected in the application of

an average royalty fee level. In order to determine whether the royalty rates in our

sample differ from average royalty rates, we compared these with royalty rates

published by Taylor and Silberston (1973) Contractor (1981), Parr (1995) and Battersby

and Grimes (2006) and found no significant differences.

Therefore, we may conclude that due to uncertainty and limited information (Caves, et

al., 1983) not only about the technology but also about the behavior of each party and

the economic consequences of this behavior, licensor and licensee will create prudent

expectations and consequently underestimate the economic potential embedded in the

licensed technology during the contract period. Additionally, each agreement can be,

like any other contract, subject to moral hazard problems. In the case of knowledge

transfer, Bessy and Brousseau (1998) argue that it might be nearly impossible to create

ex ante incentive schemes or to implement supervision mechanisms in order to avoid or

resolve hidden action problems.

5. Conclusions and further research

Our analysis of licensing agreements shows that an effective market mechanism for

technology transfer does exist. The prices for property rights of knowledge are

correlated with the breadth of rights granted. However, due to the intangible nature of

knowledge and in combination with market players that might act opportunistically,

licensing agreements are not only used to exploit the economic potential of knowledge,

but also as complex and strategic means to reduce uncertainty.

32

Our results indicate that licensor and licensee deal with two different kinds of

uncertainty. The first type of uncertainty we refer to as uncertainty during the

negotiation period can be reduced by choosing appropriate contractual terms. Dealing

with the second type – uncertainty during the contract period – seems to be more

challenging.

Prior studies have already revealed certain cross-industry differences in licensing

contracts. Since cross-licenses play a major role in the electronics industry, it would be

interesting to analyze how results will change if this research setting is applied to

another industry. Furthermore, the value significance of single property rights might

differ with regard to the economic possibilities that are linked to these rights.

Ultimately, the value of knowledge depends on generating profits from its application

and exploitation. Therefore, it is of particular interest which product-, technology- and

costumer-related factors drive the value of knowledge.

33

Figure 1: Value ranges and the life cycle of a licensing agreement

Transfer costs

Opportunitycosts

Present value of

incremental profits or

costs savings of licensse (as expected

by licensor)

Transfer costs

Opportunitycosts

Present value of

incremental cost to

substitute technology of licensse(estimated

by licensor)

Licensee‘sperspectiv

Licensor‘sperspective

Costs for substitute

technology from a

third party

Costs for litigation process

Costs for own R&D

Present value of

incremental profits or

costs savings

Licensor‘s transfer costs

Contract period

Duration?

Termination?

Effective date

Negotiation period

Rights granted?

Content?

Features?

A1 A2

B1 B2 B3 B4

34

Table 1: Descriptive statistics

Descriptives

# Words Mean Std. Devi.

Subject of the contract* Full text 2,666 1,913

Intellectual Property Rights 84.2% Preamble 299 364

Patent 15.2% Defintions 387 491

Patentportfolio 52.0% License description 262 340

Patent application 15.8% Compensation formula 275 281

Copyright 1.2% Termination rules 176 213

Invention 15.8%

Know How 3.5%

Software 10.5%

Software documentation 1.2%

Hardware 0.6%

Rights granted*

Right to produce 31.9%

Right to use 28.2%

Right to trade 31.6%

Right to sublicense 8.4%

Exclusivity 22.5%

Technology Flow back requirement 2.1%

Year of Signing

1970 - 1980 0.7%

1981 - 1990 6.3%

1991 - 2000 47.2%

2001 - 2005 45.8%

Geographical extend

Worldwide 74.6%

Non worldwide 25.4%

* Number of entries per class divided by the total number of entries in the sample

35

Table 2: Results from regression analysis

Variable Model I Model II Model III Model IV

(Constant) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 (Constant) (-1.203) (-1.355) (-0.365) (-0.303)

Definition of license 0.42 *** 0.41 *** 0.40 *** 0.44 ***Definition of license (4.814) (4.539) (4.588) (4.97) Definition of key contractual terms 0.12 0.07 0.23 * 0.24 ** Definition of key contractual terms (1.345) (0.689) (1.936) (2.031) Exclusivity of rights (0/1) 0.00 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 Exclusivity of rights (0.05) (-0.23) (-0.32) (-0.474) Cross license (0/1) 0.10 0.10 0.11 Cross license (1.058) (1.031) (1.196) Termination -0.25 ** -0.26 ***Termination (-2.573) (-2.653) Prolongation / Renewal option (0/1) -0.16 ** Duration (-2.061) N 141 141 141 141 F Value 15.29 *** 11.75 *** 11.11 *** 10.19 *** R2 0.249 0.256 0.290 0.312 R2 adj. 0.233 0.234 0.264 0.281 Delta R2 adj. 0.001 0.030 0.017 Beta values (t-values) *** p < .01 *** p < .05 *** p < .10

36

References

Alchian, A. A. and Demsetz, H., 1973. The property rights paradigm. Journal of

Economic History 33 1 16-27

Anand, B. N. and Khanna, T., 2000. The structure of licensing contracts. The Journal of

Industrial Economics 48 1 103-135

Arora, A., 1995. Licensing tacit knowledge: Intellectual property rights and the market

for know-how. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 4 41-59

Arora, A., 1997. Patents, licensing, and market structure in the chemical industry.

Research Policy 26 391-403

Arora, A. and Fosfuri, A., 2003. Licensing the market for technology. Journal of

Economic Behavior & Organization 52 2 277-296

Arrow, K. J., 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention, in:

The rate and direction of inventive activity: Economic and social factors.

Princeton University Press, Princeton

Arrow, K. J., 1971. Essays in the theory of risk-bearing. Markham Publishing

Company, Amsterdam

Arrow, K. J. and Hahn, F. H., 1971. General competitive analysis. Holden-Day, San

Francisco

Arundel, A., 2001. The relative effectiveness of patents and secrecy for appropriation.

Research Policy 30 611-624

Aulakh, P. S., Cavusgil, T. S. and Sarkar, M., 1998. Compensation in international

licensing agreements. Journal of International Business Studies 29 2 409-420

37

Ba, S., Stallert, J. and Whinston, A. B., 2001. Optimal investment in knowledge within

a firm using a market mechanism. Management Science 47 1203-1219

Barney, J. B., 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of

Management 17 1 99 - 120

Battersby, G. J. and Grimes, C. W., 2006. Licensing Royalty Rates 2006. Aspen

Publishers, New York

Bessy, C. and Brousseau, E., 1998. Technology licensing contracts, features and

diversity. International Review of Law and Economics 18 4 451-490

Boisot, M. and Child, J., 1988. The iron law of fiefs: Bureaucratic fialure and the

problem of governance in the Chinese economic reforms. Administrative Science

Quarterly 33 507-527

Bryer, L. G., 1999. International and U.S. licensing of intangibles, in: Intellectual

property in the global marketplace.

Brynjolfsson, E., 1994. Information assets, technology, and organization. Management

Science 40 12 1645-1662

Caldwell, L. K., 1975. Managing the transition to post-modern society. Public

Administration Review 35 6 567-572

Caves, R. E., Crookell, H. and Killing, P. J., 1983. The imperfect market for technology

licenses. Oxford bulletin of economics and statistics 45 3 249-267

Cho, K. R., 1988. Issues of compensation in international technology licensing.

Management International Review 28 2 70-78

Choi, C. J. and Lee, S. H., 1997. A knowledge-based view of cooperative

interorganizational relationships, in: Cooperative strategies. New Lexington

Press, San Francisco

38

Coase, R. H., 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3 4 1-44

Contractor, F. J., 1981. International technology licensing - Compensation, costs, and

negotiation. D.C. Heath and Company, Lexington, MA

Contractor, F. J., 1985. Licensing in international strategy. Greenwood Press, Westport

Demsetz, H., 1967. Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review 57

2 347-359

Drucker, P. F., 1991. The new productivity challenge. Harvard Business Review 69 6

69-79

Dyer, J. H. and Nobeoka, K., 2000. Creating and managing a high-performance

knowledge-sharing network: The Toyota case. Strategic Management Journal 21

3 345-367

Eswaran, M., 1993. Cross-licensing of competing patents as a facilitating device.

Canadian Journal of Economics 27 3 659-708

Fershtman, C. and Kamien, M. I., 1992. Cross licensing of complementary

technologies. International Journal of Industrial Organization 10 3 329-349

Fisher, R. and Ury, W., 1982. Getting to yes. Management Review 71 2 16-21

Fosfuri, A., 2006. The licensing dilemma: Understanding the determinants of the rate of

technology licensing. Strategic Management Journal 27 12 1141-1158

Foss, K. and Foss, N., J., 2005. Resources and transaction costs: How property rights

economics furthers the resource based view. Strategic Management Journal 26 6

541-553

Foss, N., J., 2002. 'Coase vs. Hayek': Economic organization and the knowledge

economy. International Journal of the Economics of Business 9 1 9-35

39

Gallini, N. T., 1984. Deterrence by market sharing: A strategic incentive for licensing.

American Economic Review 74 5 932-941

Gallini, N. T. and Winter, R. A., 1985. Licensing in the theory of innovation. RAND

Journal of Economics 16 2 237-252

Grant, R. M., 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic

Management Journal 17 Winter Special Issue 109-122

Grant, R. M., 2002. Contemporary strategy analysis. Blackwell Publishing, Oxford

Grindley, P. C. and Nickerson, J. A., 1996. Licensing and business strategy in the

chemicals industry, in: Technology licensing: Corporate strategies for

maximizing value. John Wiles & Sons, New York

Grindley, P. C. and Teece, D. J., 1997. Managing intellectual capital: Licensing and

cross-licensing in semiconductors and electronics. California Management

Review 39 2 8-41

Grudziecki, R. L. and Michel, A., 2002. Licensing and Litigation, in: Licensing best

practices - The LESI guide to strategic issues and contemporary results. John

Wiley & Sons, New York

Hayek, F. A., 1945. The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35 4

519-530

Huber, G. P., 1991. Organizational learning: The contributing process and the

literatures. Organization Science 2 1 88-115

Itami, H. and Roehl, T. W., 1987. Mobilizing invisible assets. Harvard Universitary

Press, London

Jaffe, A., 2000. The U.S. patent system in transition: policy innovation and the

innovation process. Research Policy 29 4-5 531-557

40

Kakabadse, N. K., Kouzmin, A. and Kakabadse, A., 2001. From tacit knowledge to

knowledge management: Leveraging invisible assets. Knowledge and Process

Management 8 3 137-154

Kamien, M. I. and Tauman, Y., 1986. Fee versus royalties and the private value of a

patent. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 101 3 471-491

Kamien, M. I. and Tauman, Y., 2002. Patent licensing: The inside story. The

Manchester School 70 1 7-15

Katz, M., L. and Shapiro, C., 1985. On the licensing of innovations. RAND Journal of

Economics 16 4 504-520

Katz, M., L. and Shapiro, C., 1986. How to License intangible property. The Quarterly

Journal of Economics 101 3 567-589

Kim, Y. J. and Vonortas, N. S., Year. Determinants of technology licensing, Academy

of Management Best Paper Proceedings of the Sixty-Fourth Annual Meeting

Kogut, B. and Zander, U., 1992. Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and

the replication of technology. Organization Science 3 3 383-397

Kogut, B. and Zander, U., 1993. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of

multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies 24 3 625-645

Kopits, G. F., 1976. Intra-firm royalties crossing frontiers and transfer-pricing

behaviour. The Economic Journal 86 December 791-805

Lazarus, R. S. and McCleary, R. A., 1949. Autonomic discrimination without

awareness: An interim report. Journal of Personality 18 2 171-181

Lazarus, R. S. and McCleary, R. A., 1951. Autonomic discrimination without

awareness: A study of subception. Psychological Review 58 113-122

41

Levin, R., C., Klevorick, A., K., Nelson, R., R. and Winter, S. G., 1987. Appropriating

the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on

Economic Activity 1987 Special Issue No.3 783-831

Liebeskind, J. P., 1996. Knowledge, strategy, and the theory of the firm. Strategic

Management Journal 17 93-107

Machlup, F., 1980. Knowledge: Its creation, distribution, and economic significance.

Princeton University Press,

Macho-Stadler, I., Martinez-Giralt, X. and Pérez-Castrillo, 1996. The role of

information in licensing contract design. Research Policy 25 43-57

Manfroy, W., 2002. Expanding business of licensing, in: Licensing best practices - The

LESI guide to strategic issues and contemporary results. John Wiley & Sons,

New York

Mansfield, E., Schwartz, M. and Wagner, S., 1981. Imitation costs and patents: An

empirical study. The Economic Journal 91 December 907-918

Mansfield, E., 1986. Patents and innovations: An empirical study. Management Science

32 2 173-181

Martin, X. and Salomon, R., 2003. Tacitness, learning, and international expansion: A

study of foreign direct investment in a knowledge-intensive industry.

Organization Science 14 3 297-311

McEvily, S., K., Eisenhardt, K., M. and Prescott, J. E., 2004. The globaly acquisition,

leverage, and protection of technological competencies. Strategic Management

Journal 25 713 - 722

42

Merwin, M. J. and Warner, C. M., 1996. Techniques for obtaining and analyzing

external license agreements, in: Technology licensing - Corporate strategies for

maximizing value. John Wiley & Sons, New York

Mottner, S. and Johnson, J. P., 2000. Motivations and risks in international licensing: A

review and implications for licensing to transitional and emerging economies.

Journal of World Business 35 2 171-188

Mudambi, R. and Navarra, P., 2004. Is knowledge power? Knowledge flows, subsidiary

power and rent seeking within MNCs. Journal of International Business Studies

35 385-406

Nagaoka, S. and Kwon, U. H., 2006. The incidence of cross-licensing: A theory and

new evidence of the firm and contract level determinants. Research Policy 35 9

1347-1361

Nahapiet, J. and Ghoshal, S., 1998. Social capital, intellectual capital, and the

organizational advantage. Academy of Management Review 23 2 242-266

Nelson, R., R., 1990. Capitalism as an engine of progress. Research Policy 19 193-214

Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. G., 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. The

Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

Nickerson, J. A., 1996. Strategic objectives supported by licensing, in: Technology

licensing - Corporate strategies for maximizing value. John Wiley & Sons Inc.,

New York

Nonaka, I., 1991. The knowledge-creating company. Harvard Business Review 69 6 96-

104

Nonaka, I., 1994. A dynamic theory of organizational knowledge creation. Organization

Science 5 1 14-37

43

Nonaka, I. and Takeuchi, H., 1995. The knowledge-creating company - How Japanese

companies create the dynamics of innovation. Oxford University Press, New

York

Ordover, J. A., 1991. A patent system for both diffusion and exclusion. Journal of

Economic Perspectives 5 1 43-60

Parr, R. L., 1995. Royalty rates in general and on average. The Journal of Technology

Transfer 20 2 22-25

Penrose, E. T., 1959. The growth of the firm. Basil Blackwell, Oxford

Perlitz, M., 1980. Compensatory arrangements in international licensing agreements:

Effects on market penetration abroad, foreign pricing policy, and conflict areas

between licensee and licensor. Management International Review 20 1 75-83

Poddar, S. and Sinha, U. B., 2004. On patent licensing in spatial competition. The

Economic Record 80 249 208-218

Polanyi, M., 1958. Personal Knowledge - Towards a post-critical philosophy. Routledge

& Kegan Paul, London

Polanyi, M., 1966. The tacit dimension. Doubleday & company, New York

Quinn, J. B., 1992. Intelligent Entreprise. The Free Press, New York

Rabin, M., 1993. Information and the control of productive assets. Journal of law,

economics and organization 9 1 51-76

Ramsay, J. T., 2002. Dreadful drafting: The do's and don'ts of licensing agreements, in:

Licensing Best Practices: The LSI Guide to Strategic Issues and Contemporary

Realities. John Wiles & Sons, New York

44

Reitzig, M., 2004. The private values of 'thickets' and 'fences': Towards an updated

picture of the use of patents across industries. Economics of Innovation and New

Technology 13 5 457-476

Rockett, K. E., 1990. Choosing the competition and patent licensing. RAND Journal of

Economics 21 1 161-171

Rostoker, M. D., 1983. A survey of corporate licensing. The Journal of Law and

Technology 24 59-92

Saracho, A. I., 2002. Patent licensing under strategic delegation. Journal of Economics

& Management Strategy 11 2 225-251

Shapiro, C., 1985. Patent licensing and R&D rivalry. American Economic Review 75 2

25-30

Sherry, E. F. and Teece, D. J., 2004. Royalties, evlving patent rights, and the value of

innovation. Research Policy 33 179-191

Spender, J.-C., 1996. Making knowledge the basis of a dynamic theory of the firm.

Strategic Management Journal 17 Winter Special Issue 45-62

Srnka, K. J. and Koeszegi, S. T., 2007. From words to numbers: How to transform

qualitative data into meaningful quantitative results. Schmalenbach Business

Review 59 29-57

Sullivan, S. P., 1996. The importance of context in the derivation of royalty rates, in:

Technology licensing: Corporate strategies for maximizing value. John Wiley &

Sons, New York

Taylor, C. T. and Silberston, Z. A., 1973. The economic impact of the patent system - A

study of the British experience. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

45

Teece, D. J., 1977. Technology transfer by multinational firms: The resource cost of

transferring technological know-how. The Economic Journal 87 346 242-261

Teece, D. J., 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration,

collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy 15 285-305

Teece, D. J., 1998. Capturing value from knowledge assets: The new economy, markets

for know-how, and intangible assets. California Management Review 40 3 55-79

Winter, S. G., 1987. Knowledge and competence as strategic assets, in: The competitive

challenge - Strategies for industrial innovation and renewal. Ballinger,

Cambridge, MA

Winter, S. G., 2006. The logic of appropriability: From Schumpeter to Arrow to Teece.

Research Policy 35 8 1100 - 1106

Zack, M. H., 1999. Developing a knowledge strategy. California Management Review

41 3 125-145